cocktail party level of reasoning when there's data or other strong evidence that can be directly applied. This happens throughout the BE memo even though, at other times, when the BC memo has some moderately plausible reasoning, the BE memo's counter is that we should not accept such reasoning and need to look at the data and not just reason about things in the abstract. The BE memo heavily leans on the concept that we must rely on data over reasoning and calls arguments from the BC memo that aren't rooted in rigorous data anecdotal, "beyond speculation", etc., but BE memo only does this in cases where knowledge or reasoning might lead one to conclude that there was some kind of barrier to competition. When the data indicates that Google's behavior creates some kind of barrier in the market, the authors of BE memo ignore all relevant data and instead rely on reasoning over data even when the reasoning is weak and has the character of the Boies argument we referenced earlier. One could argue that the standard of evidence for pursuing an antitrust case should be stronger the standard of evidence for not pursuing one, but if the asymmetry observed here were for that reason, the BE memo could have listed areas where the evidence wasn't strong enough without making its own weak assertions in the face of stronger evidence. An example of this is the discussion of the impact of mobile defaults.
The BE memo argues that defaults are essentially worthless and have little to no impact, saying multiple times that users can switch with just "a few taps", adding that this takes "a few seconds" and that, therefore, "[t]hese are trivial switching costs". The most obvious and direct argument piece of evidence on the impact of defaults is the amount of money Google pays to retain its default status. In a 2023 antitrust action, it was revealed that Google paid Apple $26.3B to retain its default status in 2021. As of this writing, Apple's P/E ratio is 29.53. If we think of this payment as, at the margin, pure profit and having default status is as worthless as indicated by the BE memo, a naive estimate of how much this is worth to Apple is that it can account for something like $776B of Apple's $2.9T market cap. Or, looking at this from Google's standpoint, Google's P/E ratio is 27.49, so Google is willing to give up $722B of its $2.17T market cap. Google is willing to pay this to be the default search for something like 25% to 30% of phones in the world. This calculation is too simplistic, but there's no reasonable adjustment that could give anyone the impression that the value of being the default is as trivial as claimed by the BE memo. For reference, a $776B tech company would be 7th most valuable publicly traded U.S. tech company and the 8th most valuable publicly traded U.S. company (behind Meta/Facebook and Berkshire Hathaway, but ahead of Eli Lilly). Another reference is that YouTube's ad revenue in 2021 was $28.8B. It would be difficult to argue that spending one YouTube worth of revenue, in profit, in order to retain default status makes sense if, in practice, user switching costs are trivial and defaults don't matter. If we look for publicly available numbers close to 2012 instead of 2021, in 2013, TechCrunch reported a rumor that Google was paying Apple $1B/yr for search status and a lawsuit then revealed that Google paid Apple $1B for default search status in 2014. This is not longer after these memos are written and $1B/yr is still a non-trivial amount of money and it belies the BE memo's claim that mobile is unimportant and that defaults don't matter because user switching costs are trivial.
It's curious that, given the heavy emphasis in the BE memo on not trusting plausible reasoning and having to rely on empirical data, that BE staff appeared to make no attempt to find out how much Google was paying for its default status (a memo by a director who agrees with BE staff suggests that someone ought to check on this number, but there's no evidence that this was done and the FTC investigation was dropped shortly afterwards). Given the number of internal documents the FTC was able to obtain, it seems unlikely that the FTC would not have been able to obtain this number from either Apple or Google. But, even if it were the case that the number were unobtainable, it's prima facie implausible that defaults don't matter and switching costs are low in practice. If FTC staff interviewed product-oriented engineers and PMs or looked at the history of products in tech, so in order to make this case, BE staff had to ignore or avoid finding out how much Google was paying for default status, not talk to product-focused engineers, PM, or leadership, and also avoid learning about the tech industry.
One could make the case that, while defaults are powerful, companies have been able to overcome being non-default, which could lead to a debate on exactly how powerful defaults are. For example, one might argue about the impact of defaults when Google Chrome became the dominant browser and debate how much of it was due to Chrome simply being a better browser than IE, Opera, and Firefox, how much was due to blunders by Microsoft that Google is unlikely to repeat in search, how much was due to things like tricking people into making Chrome default via a bundle deal with badware installers and how much was due to pressuring people into setting Chrome is default via google.com. That's an interesting discussion where a reasonable person with an understanding of the industry could take either side of the debate, unlike the claim that defaults basically don't matter at all and user switching costs are trivial in practice, which is not plausible even without access to the data on how much Google pays Apple and others to retain default status. And as of the 2020 DoJ case against Google, roughly half of Google searches occur via a default search that Google pays for.
Another repeated error, closely related to the one above, is bringing up marketing statements, press releases, or other statements that are generally understood to be exaggerations, and relying on these as if they're meaningful statements of fact. For example, the BE memo states:
Microsoft's public statements are not consistent with statements made to antitrust regulators. Microsoft CEO Steve Ballmer stated in a press release announcing the search agreement with Yahoo: "This agreement with Yahoo! will provide the scale we need to deliver even more rapid advances in relevancy and usefulness. Microsoft and Yahoo! know there's so much more that search could be. This agreement gives us the scale and resources to create the future of search"
This is the kind of marketing pablum that generally accompanies an acquisition or partnership. Because this kind of meaningless statement is common across many industries, one would expect regulators, even ones with no understanding of tech, to recognize this as marketing and not give it as much or more weight as serious evidence.
A few interesting tidbits
Now that we've covered the main classes of errors observed in the memos, we'll look at a tidbits from the memos.
Between the approval of the compulsory process on June 3rd 2011 and the publication of the BC memo dated August 8th 2012, staff received 9.5M pages of documents across 2M docs and said they reviewed "many thousands of these documents", so staff were only able to review a small fraction of the documents.
Prior to the FTC investigation, there were a number of lawsuits related to the same issues, and all were dismissed, some with arguments that would, if they were taken as broad precedent, make it difficult for any litigation to succeed. In SearchKing v. Google, plaintiffs alleged that Google unfairly demoted their results but it was ruled that Google's rankings are constitutionally protected opinion and even malicious manipulation of rankings would not expose Google to liability. In Kinderstart v. Google, part of the ruling was that Google search is not an essential facility for vertical providers (such as Yelp, eBay, and Expedia). Since the memos are ultimately about legal proceedings, there is, of course, extensive discussion of Verizon v. Trinko and Aspen Skiing Co. v. Aspen Highlands Skiing Corp and the implications thereof.
As of the writing of the BC memo, 96% of Google's $38B in revenue was from ads, mostly from search ads. The BC memo makes the case that other forms of advertising, other than social media ads, only have limited potential for growth. That's certainly wrong in retrospect. For example, video ads are a significant market. YouTube's ad revenue was $28.8B in 2021 (a bit more than what Google pays to Apple to retain default search status), Twitch supposedly generated another $2B-$3B in video revenue, and a fair amount of video ad revenue goes directly from sponsors to streamers without passing through YouTube and Twitch, e.g., the #137th largest streamer on Twitch was offered $10M/yr stream online gambling for 30 minutes a day, and he claims that the #42 largest streamer, who he personally knows, was paid $10M/mo from online gambling sponsorships. And this isn't just apparent in retrospect — even at the time, there were strong signs that video would become a major advertising market. It happens that those same signs also showed that Google was likely to dominate the market for video ads, but it's still the case that the specific argument here was overstated.
In general, the BC memo seems to overstate the expected primacy of search ads as well as how distinct a market search ads are, claiming that other online ad spend is not a substitute in any way and, if anything, is a complement. Although one might be able to reasonably argue that search ads are a somewhat distinct market and the elasticity of substitution is low once you start moving a significant amount of your ad spend away from search, the degree to which the BC memo makes this claim is a stretch. Search ads and other ad budgets being complements and not substitutes is a very different position than I've heard from talking to people about how ad spend is allocated in practice. Perhaps one can argue that it makes sense to try to make a strong case here in light of Person V. Google, where Judge Fogel of the Northern District of California criticized the plaintiff's market definition, finding no basis for distinguishing "search advertising market" from the larger market for internet advertising, which likely foreshadows an objection that would be raised in any future litigation. However, as someone who's just trying to understand the facts of the matter at hand and the veracity of the arguments, the argument here seems dubious.
For Google's integrated products like local search and product search (formerly Froogle), the BC memo claims that if Google treated its own properties like other websites, the products wouldn't be ranked and Google artificially placed their own vertical competitors above organic offerings. The webspam team declined to include Froogle results because the results are exactly the kind of thing that Google removes from the index because it's spammy, saying "[o]ur algorithms specifically look for pages like these to either demote or remove from the index". Bill Brougher, product manager for web search said "Generally we like to have the destination pages in the index, not the aggregated pages. So if our local pages are lists of links to other pages, it's more important that we have the other pages in the index". After the webspam team was overruled and the results were inserted, the ads team complained that the less clicked (and implied to be lower quality) results would lead to a loss of $154M/yr. The response to this essentially contained the same content as the BC memo's argument on the importance of scale and why Google's actions to deprive competitors of scale are costly:
We face strong competition and must move quickly. Turning down onebox would hamper progress as follows - Ranking: Losing click data harms ranking; [t]riggering Losing CTR and google.com query distribution data triggering accuracy; [c]omprehensiveness: Losing traffic harms merchant growth and therefore comprehensiveness; [m]erchant cooperation: Losing traffic reduces effort merchants put into offer data, tax, & shipping; PR: Turning off onebox reduces Google's credibility in commerce; [u]ser awareness: Losing shopping-related UI on google.com reduces awareness of Google's shopping features
Normally, CTR is used as a strong signal to rank results, but this would've resulted in a low ranking for Google's own vertical properties, so "Google used occurrence of competing vertical websites to automatically boost the ranking of its own vertical properties above that of competitors" — if a comparison shopping site was relevant, Google would insert Google Product search above any rival, and if a local search site like Yelp or CitySearch was relevant, Google automatically returned Google Local at top of SERP.
Additionally, in order to see content for Google local results, Google took Yelp content and integrated it into Google Places. When Yelp observed this was happening, they objected to this and Google threatened to ban Yelp from traditional Google search results and further threatened to ban any vertical provider that didn't allow its content to be used in Google Places. Marissa Mayer testified that it was, from a technical standpoint, extraordinarily difficult to remove Yelp from Google Places without also removing Yelp from traditional organic search results. But when Yelp sent a cease and desist letter, Google was able to remove Yelp results immediately, seemingly indicating that it was less difficult than claimed. Google then claimed that it was technically infeasible to remove Yelp from Google Places without removing Yelp from the "local merge" interface on SERP. BC staff believe this claim is false as well, and Marissa Mayer later admitted in a hearing that this claim was false and that Google was concerned about the consequences of allowing sites to opt out of Google Places while staying in "local merge". There was also a very similar story with Amazon results and product search. As noted above, the BE memo's counterargument to all of this is that Google traffic is "very small and not statistically significant"
The BC memo claims that the activities above both reduced incentives of companies Yelp, City Search, Amazon, etc., to invest in the area and also reduced the incentives for new companies to form in this area. This seems true. In addition to the evidence presented in the BC memo (which goes beyond what was summarized above), if you just talked to founders looking for an idea or VCs around the time of the FTC investigation, there had already been a real movement away from founding and funding companies like Yelp because it was understood that Google could seriously cripple any similar company in this space by cutting off its air supply.
We'll defer to the appendix BC memo discussion on the AdWords API restrictions that specifically disallow programmatic porting of campaigns to other platforms, such as Bing. But one interesting bit there is that Google was apparently aware of the legal sensitivity of this matter, so meeting notes and internal documentation on the topic are unusually incomplete. On one meeting, apparently the most informative written record BC staff were able to find consists of a message from Director of PM Richard Holden to SVP of ads Susan Wojicki which reads, "We didn't take notes for obvious reasons hence why I'm not elaborating too much here in email but happy to brief you more verbally".
We'll also defer a detailed discussion of the BC memo comments on Google's exclusive and restrictive syndication agreements to the appendix, except for a couple of funny bits. One is that Google claims they were unaware of the terms and conditions in their standard online service agreements. In particular, the terms and conditions contained a "preferred placement" clause, which a number of parties believe is a de facto exclusivity agreement. When FTC staff questioned Google's VP of search services about this term, the VP claimed they were not aware of this term. Afterwards, Google sent a letter to Barbara Blank of the FTC explaining that they were removing the preferred placement clause in the standard online agreement.
Another funny bit involves Google's market power and how it allowed them to collect an increasingly large share of revenue for themselves and decrease the revenue share their partner received. Only a small number of Google's customers who were impacted by this found this concerning. Those that did find it concerning were some of the largest and most sophisticated customers (such as Amazon and IAC); their concern was that Google's restrictive and exclusive provisions would increase Google's dominance over Bing/Microsoft and allow them to dictate worse terms to customers. Even as Google was executing a systematic strategy to reduce revenue share to customers, which could only be possible due to their dominance of the market, most customers appeared to either not understand the long-term implications of Google's market power in this area or the importance of the internet.
For example, Best Buy didn't find this concerning because Best Buy viewed their website and the web as a way for customers to find presale information before entering a store and Walmart didn't find didn't find this concerning because they viewed the web as an extension to brick and mortar retail. It seems that the same lack of understanding of the importance of the internet which led Walmart and Best Buy to express their lack of concern over Google's dominance here also led to these retailers, which previously had a much stronger position than Amazon, falling greatly behind in both online and overall profit. Walmart later realized its error here and acquired Jet.com for $3.3B in 2016 and also seriously (relative to other retailers) funded programmers to do serious tech work inside Walmart. Since Walmart started taking the internet seriously, it's made a substantial comeback online and has averaged a 30% CAGR in online net sales since 2018, but taking two decades to mount a serious response to Amazon's online presence has put Walmart solidly behind Amazon in online retail despite nearly a decade of serious investment and Best Buy has still not been able to mount an effective response to Amazon after three decades.
The BE memo uses the lack of concern on the part of most customers as evidence that the exclusive and restrictive conditions Google dictated here were not a problem but, in retrospect, it's clear that it was only a lack of understanding of the implications of online business that led customers to be unconcerned here. And when the BE memo refers to the customers who understood the implications here as sophisticated, that's relative to people in lines of business where leadership tended to not understand the internet. While these customers are sophisticated by comparison to a retailer that took two decades to mount a serious response to the threat Amazon poses to their business, if you just talked to people in the tech industry at the time, you wouldn't need to find a particularly sophisticated individual to find someone who understood what was going on. It was generally understood that retail revenue and even moreso, retail profit was going to move online, and you'd have to find someone who was extremely unusually out of the loop to find someone who didn't at least roughly understand the implications here.
There's a lengthy discussion on search and scale in both the BC and BE memos. On this topic, the BE memo seems wrong and the implications of the BC memo are, if not subtle, at least not obvious. Let's start with the BE memo because that one's simpler to discuss, although we'll very briefly discuss the argument in the BC memo in order to frame the discussion in the BE memo. A rough sketch of the argument in the BC memo is that there are multiple markets (search, ads) where scale has a significant impact on product quality. Google's own documents acknowledge this "virtuous cycle" where having more users lets you serve better ads, which gives you better revenue for ads and, likewise in search, having more scale gives you more data which can be used to improve results, which leads to user growth. And for search in particular, the BC memo claims that click data from users is of high importance and that more data allows for better results.
The BE memo claims that this is not really the case. On the importance of click data, the BE memo raises two large objections. First, that this is "contrary to the history of the general search market" and second, that "it is also contrary to the evidence that factors such as the quality of the web crawler and web index; quality of the search algorithm; and the type of content included in the search results [are as important or more important].
Of the first argument, the BE memo elaborates with a case that's roughly "Google used to be smaller than it is today, and the click data at the time was sufficient, therefore being as large as Google used to be means that you have sufficient click data". Independent of knowledge of the tech industry, this seems like a strange line of reasoning. "We now produce a product that's 1/3 as good as our competitor for the same price, but that should be fine because our competitor previously produced a product that's 1/3 as good as their current product when the market was less mature and no one was producing a better product" is generally not going to be a winning move. That's especially true in markets where there's a virtuous cycle between market share and product quality, like in search.
The second argument also seems like a strange argument to make even without knowledge of the tech industry in that it's a classic fallacious argument. It's analogous to saying something like "the BC memo claims that it's important for cars to have a right front tire, but that's contrary to evidence that it's at least as important for a car to have a left front tire and a right rear tire". The argument is even less plausible if you understand tech, especially search. Calling out the quality of the search algorithm as distinct doesn't feel quite right because scale and click data directly feed into algorithm development (and this is discussed at some length in the BE memo — the authors of the BC memo surely had access to the same information and, from their writing, seem to have had access to the argument). And as someone who's worked on search indexing, as much as I'd like to be agree with the BE memo and say that indexing is as important or more important than ranking, I have to admit that indexing is an easier and less important problem than ranking and likewise for crawling vs. ranking. This was generally understood at the time so, given the number of interviews FTC staff did, the authors of the BE memo should've known this as well. Moreover, given the "history of the general search market" which the BE memo refers to, even without talking to engineers, this should've been apparent.
For example, Cuil was famous for building a larger index than Google. While that's not a trivial endeavor, at the time, quite a few people had the expertise to build an index that rivaled Google's index in raw size or whatever other indexing metric you prefer, if given enough funding for a serious infra startup. Cuil and other index-focused attempts failed because having a large index without good search ranking is worth little. While it's technically true that having good ranking with a poor index is also worth little, this is not something we've really seen in practice because ranking is the much harder problem and a company that's competent to build a good search ranker will, as a matter of course, have a good enough index and good enough crawling.
As for the case in the BC memo, I don't know what the implications should be. The BC memo correctly points out that increased scale greatly improves search quality, that the extra data Bing got from the Yahoo greatly increased search quality and increased CTR, that further increased scale should be expected to continue to provide high return, that the costs of creating a competitor to Google are high (Bing was said to be losing $2B/yr at the time and was said to be spending $4.5B/yr "developing its algorithms and building the physical capacity necessary to operate Bing"), and that Google undertook actions that might be deemed anticompetitive which disadvantaged Bing's compared to the counterfactual world where Google did not take those actionts, and they make a similar case for ads. However, despite the strength of the stated BC memo case and the incorrectness of the stated BE memo case, the BE memo's case is correct in spirit, in that there are actions Microsoft could've taken but did not in order to compete much more effectively in search and one could argue that the FTC shouldn't be in the business of rescuing a company from competing ineffectively.
Personally, I don't think it's too interesting to discuss the position of the BC memo vs. the BE memo at length because the positions the BE memo takes seem extremely weak. It's not fair to call it a straw man because it's a real position, and one that carried the day at the FTC, but the decision to take action or not seemed more about philosophy than the arguments in the memos. But we can discuss what else might've been done.
What might've happened
What happened after the FTC declined to pursue antitrust action was that Microsoft effectively defunded Bing as a serious bet, taking resources that could've gone to continuing to fund a very expensive fight against Google, and moving them to other bets that it deemed to be higher ROI. The big bets Microsoft pursued were Azure, Office, and HoloLens (and arguably Xbox). Hololens was a pie-in-the-sky bet, but Azure and Office were lines of business where Microsoft could, instead of fighting an uphill battle where their competitor can use its dominance in related markets to push around competitors, Microsoft could fight downhill battles where they can use their dominance in related markets to push around competitors, resulting in a much higher return per dollar invested. As someone who worked on Bing and thought that BIng had the potential to seriously compete with Google given sustained, unprofitable, heavy investment, I find that disappointing but also likely the correct business decision. If you look at any particular submarket, like Teams vs. Slack, the Microsoft product doesn't need to be nearly as good as the competing product to take over the market, which is the opposite of the case in search, where Google's ability to push competitors around means that Bing would have to be much better than Google to attain marketshare parity.
Based on their public statements, Biden's DoJ Antitrust AAG appointee, Jonathan Kanter, would argue for pursuing antitrust action under the circumstances, as would Biden's FTC commissioner and chair appointee Lina Khan. Prior to her appointment as FTC commissioner and chair, Khan was probably best known for writing Amazon's Antitrust Paradox, which has been influential as well as controversial. Obama appointees, who more frequently agreed with the kind of reasoning from the BE memo, would have argued against antitrust action and the investigation under discussion was stopped on their watch. More broadly, they argued against the philosophy driving Kanter and Khan. Obama's FTC Commissioner appointee, GMU economist and legal scholar Josh Wright actually wrote a rebuttal titled "Requiem for a Paradox: The Dubious Rise and Inevitable Fall of Hipster Antitrust", a scathing critique of Khan's position.
If, in 2012, the FTC and DoJ were run by Biden appointees instead of Obama appointees, what difference would that have made? We can only speculate, but one possibility would be that they would've taken action and then lost, as happened with the recent cases against Meta and Microsoft which seem like they would not have been undertaken under an Obama FTC and DoJ. Under Biden appointees, there's been much more vigorous use of the laws that are on the books, the Sherman Act, the Clayton Act, the FTC Act, the Robinson–Patman Act, as well as "smaller" antitrust laws, but the opinion of the courts hasn't changed under Biden and this has led to a number of unsuccessful antitrust cases in tech. Both the BE and BC memos dedicate significant space to whether or not a particular line of reasoning will hold up in court. Biden's appointees are much less concerned with this than previous appointees and multiple people in the DoJ and the FTC are on the record saying things like "it is our duty to enforce the law", meaning that when they see violations of the antitrust laws that were put into place by elected officials, it's their job to pursue these violations even if courts may not agree with the law.
Another possibility is that there would've been some action, but the action would've been in line with most corporate penalties we see. Something like a small fine that costs the company an insignificant fraction of marginal profit they made from their actions, or some kind of consent decree (basically a cease and desist), where the company will be required to stop doing specific actions while keeping their marketshare, keeping the main thing they wanted to gain, a massive advantage in a market dominated by network effects. Perhaps there will be a few more meetings where "[w]e didn't take notes for obvious reasons" to work around the new limitations and business as usual will continue. Given the specific allegations in the FTC memos and the attitudes of the courts at the time, my guess is that something like this second set of possibilities would've been the most likely outcome had the FTC proceeded with their antitrust investigation instead of dropping it, some kind of nominal victory that makes little to no difference in practice. Given how long it takes for these cases to play out, it's overwhelmingly likely that Microsoft would've already scaled back its investment in Bing and moved Bing from a subsidized bet it was trying to grow to a profitable business it wanted to keep by the time any decision was made. There are a number of cases that were brought by other countries which had remedies that were in line with what we might've expected if the FTC investigation continued. On Google using market power in mobile to push software Google wants to nearly all Android phones, an EU and was nominally successful but made little to no difference in practice. Cristina Caffara of the Centre for Economic Policy Research characterized this as
Europe has failed to drive change on the ground. Why? Because we told them, don't do it again, bad dog, don't do it again. But in fact, they all went and said 'ok, ok', and then went out, ran back from the back door and did it again, because they're smarter than the regulator, right? And that's what happens.
So, on the tying case, in Android, the issue was, don't tie again so they say, "ok, we don't tie". Now we got a new system. If you want Google Play Store, you pay $100. But if you want to put search in every entry point, you get a discount of $100 ... the remedy failed, and everyone else says, "oh, that's a nice way to think about it, very clever"
Another pair of related cases are Yandex's Russian case on mobile search defaults and a later EU consent decree. In 2015, Yandex brought a suit about mobile default status on Android in Russia, which was settled by adding a "choice screen" which has users pick their search engine without preferencing a default. This immediately caused Yandex to start gaining marketshare on Google and Yandex eventually surpassed Google in marketshare in Russia according to statcounter. In 2018, the EU required a similar choice screen in Europe, which didn't make much of a difference, except maybe sort of in the Czech republic. There are a number of differences between the situation in Russia and in the EU. One, arguably the most important, is that when Yandex brought the case against Google in Russia, Yandex was still fairly competitive, with marketshare in the high 30% range. At the time of the EU decision in 2018, Bing was the #2 search engine in Europe, with about 3.6% marketshare. Giving consumers a choice when one search engine completely dominates the market can be expected to have fairly little impact. One argument the BE memo heavily relies on is the idea that, if we intervene in any way, that could have bad effects down the line, so we should be very careful and probably not do anything, just in case. But in these winner-take-most markets with such strong network effects, there's a relatively small window in which you can cheaply intervene. Perhaps, and this is highly speculative, if the FTC required a choice screen in 2012, Bing would've continued to invest enough to at least maintain its marketshare against Google.
For verticals, in shopping, the EU required some changes to how Google presents results in 2017. This appears to have had little to no impact, being both perhaps 5-10 years too late and also a trivial change that wouldn't have made much difference even if enacted a decade earlier. The 2017 ruling came out of a case that started in 2010, and in the 7 years it took to take action, Google managed to outcompete its vertical competitors, making them barely relevant at best.
Another place we could look is at the Microsoft antitrust trial. That's a long story, at least as long as this document, but to very briefly summarize, in 1990, the FTC started an investigation over Microsoft's allegedly anticompetitive conduct. A vote to continue the investigation ended up in a 2-2 tie, causing the investigation to be closed. The DoJ then did its own investigation, which led to a consent decree that was generally considered to not be too effective. There was then a 1998 suit by the DoJ about Microsoft's use of monopoly power in the browser market, which initially led to a decision to break Microsoft up. But, on appeal, the breakup was overturned, which led to a settlement in 2002. A major component of the 1998 case was about browser bundling and Microsoft's attack on Netscape. By the time the case was settled, in 2002, Netscape was effectively dead. The parts of the settlements having to do with interoperability were widely regarded as ineffective at the time, not only because Netscape was dead, but because they weren't going to be generally useful. A number of economists took the same position as the BE memo, that no intervention should've happened at the time and that any intervention is dangerous and could lead to a fettering of innovation. Nobel Prize winning economist Milton Friedman wrote a Cato Policy Forum essay titled "The Business Community's Suicidal Impulse", predicting that tech companies calling for antitrust action against Microsoft were committing suicide, and that a critical threshold had been passed and that this would lead to the bureaucratization of Silicon Valley
When I started in this business, as a believer in competition, I was a great supporter of antitrust laws; I thought enforcing them was one of the few desirable things that the government could do to promote more competition. But as I watched what actually happened, I saw that, instead of promoting competition, antitrust laws tended to do exactly the opposite, because they tended, like so many government activities, to be taken over by the people they were supposed to regulate and control. And so over time I have gradually come to the conclusion that antitrust laws do far more harm than good and that we would be better off if we didn’t have them at all, if we could get rid of them. But we do have them.
Under the circumstances, given that we do have antitrust laws, is it really in the self-interest of Silicon Valley to set the government on Microsoft? ... you will rue the day when you called in the government. From now on the computer industry, which has been very fortunate in that it has been relatively free of government intrusion, will experience a continuous increase in government regulation. Antitrust very quickly becomes regulation. Here again is a case that seems to me to illustrate the suicidal impulse of the business community.
In retrospect, we can see that this wasn't correct and, if anything, was the opposite of correct. On the idea that even attempting antirust action against Microsoft would lead to an inevitable increase in government intervention, we saw the opposite, a two-decade long period of relatively light regulation and antitrust activity. And in terms of the impacts on innovation, although the case against Microsoft was too little and too late to save Netscape, Google's success appears to be causally linked to the antitrust trial. At one point, in the early days of Google, when Google had no market power and Microsoft effectively controlled how people access the internet, Microsoft internally discussed proposals aimed at killing Google. One proposal involved redirecting users who tried to navigate to Google to Bing (at the time, called MSN Search, and of course this was before Chrome existed and IE dominated the browser market). Another idea was to put up a big scary warning that warned users that Google was dangerous, much like the malware warnings browsers have today. Gene Burrus, a lawyer for Microsoft at the time, stated that Microsoft chose not to attempt to stop users from navigating to google.com due to concerns about further antitrust action after they'd been through nearly a decade of serious antitrust scrutiny. People at both Google and Microsoft who were interviewed about this both believe that Microsoft would've killed Google had they done this so, in retrospect, we can see that Milton Friedman was wrong about the impacts of the Microsoft antitrust investigations and that one can make the case that it's only because of the antitrust investigations that web 1.0 companies like Google and Facebook were able to survive, let alone flourish.
Another possibility is that a significant antitrust action would've been undertaken, been successful, and been successful quickly enough to matter. It's possible that, by itself, a remedy wouldn't have changed the equation for Bing vs. Google, but if a reasonable remedy was found and enacted, it still could've been in time to keep Yelp and other vertical sites as serious concerns and maybe even spur more vertical startups. And in the hypothetical universe where people with the same philosophy as Biden's appointees were running the FTC and the DoJ, we might've also seen antitrust action against Microsoft in markets where they can leverage their dominance in adjacent markets, making Bing a more appealing area for continued heavy investment. Perhaps that would've resulted in Bing being competitive with Google and the aforementioned concerns that "sophisticated customers" like Amazon and IAC had may not have come to pass. With antitrust against Microsoft and other large companies that can use their dominance to push competitors around, perhaps Slack would still be an independent product and we'd see more startups in enterprise tools (a number of commenters believe that Slack was basically forced into being acquired because it's too difficult to compete with Teams given Microsoft's dominance in related markets). And Slack continuing to exist and innovate is small potatoes — the larger hypothetical impact would be all of the new startups and products that would be created that no one even bothers to attempt because they're concerned that a behemoth with an integrated bundle like Microsoft would crush their standalone product. If you add up all of these, if not best-case, at least very-good-case outcomes for antitrust advocates, one could argue that consumers and businesses would be better off. But, realistically, it's hard to see how this very-good-case set of outcomes could have come to pass.
Coming back to the FTC memo, if we think about what it would take to put together a set of antitrust actions that actually fosters real competition, that seems extraordinarily difficult. A number of the more straightforward and plausible sounding solutions are off the table for political reasons, due to legal precedent, or due to arguments like the Boies argument we referenced or some of the arguments in the BE memo that are clearly incorrect, but appear to be convincing to very important people.
For the solutions that seem to be on the table, weighing the harms caused by them is non-trivial. For example, let's say the FTC mandated a mobile and desktop choice screen in 2012. This would've killed Mozilla in fairly short order unless Mozilla completely changed its business model because Mozilla basically relies on payments from Google for default status to survive. We've seen with Opera that even when you have a superior browser that introduces features that other browsers later copy, which has better performance than other browsers, etc., you can't really compete with free browsers when you have a paid browser. So then we would've quickly been down to IE/Edge and Chrome. And in terms of browser engines, just Chrome after not too long as Edge is now running Chrome under the hood. Maybe we can come up with another remedy that allows for browser competition as well, but the BE memo isn't wrong to note that antitrust remedies can cause other harms.
Another example which highlights the difficulty of crafting a politically suitable remedy are the restrictions the Bundeskartellamt imposed against Facebook, which have to do with user privacy and use of data (for personalization, ranking, general ML training, etc.), which is considered an antitrust issue in Germany. Michal Gal, Professor and Director of the Forum on Law and Markets at the University of Haifa pointed out that, of course Facebook, in response to the rulings, is careful to only limit its use of data if Facebook detects that you're German. If the concern is that ML models are trained on user data, this doesn't do much to impair Facebook's capability. Hypothetically, if Germany had a tech scene that was competitive with American tech and German companies were concerned about a similar ruling being leveled against them, this would be disadvantageous to nascent German companies that initially focus on the German market before expanding internationally. For Germany, this is only a theoretical concern as, other than SAP, no German company has even approached the size and scope of large American tech companies. But when looking at American remedies and American regulation, this isn't a theoretical concern, and some lawmakers will want to weigh the protection of American consumers against the drag imposed on American firms when compared to Korean, Chinese, and other foreign firms that can grow in local markets with fewer privacy concerns before expanding to international markets. This concern, if taken seriously, could be used to argue against nearly any pro-antitrust action argument.
What can we do going forward?
This document is already long enough, so we'll defer a detailed discussion of policy specifics for another time, but in terms of high-level actions, one thing that seems like it would be helpful is to have tech people intimately involved in crafting remedies and regulation as well as during investigations2. From the directors memos on the 2011-2021 FTC investigation that are publicly available, it would appear this was not done because the arguments from the BE memos that wouldn't pass the sniff test for a tech person appear to have been taken seriously. Another example is the one EU remedy that Cristina Caffara noted was immediately worked around by Google, in a way that many people in tech would find to be a delightful "hack".
There's a long history of this kind of "hacking the system" being lauded in tech going back to before anyone called it "tech" and it was just physics and electrical engineering. To pick a more recent example, one of the reasons Sam Altman become President of Y Combinator, which eventually led to him becoming CEO of Open AI was that Paul Graham admired his ability to hack systems; in his 2010 essay on founders, under the section titled "Naughtiness", Paul wrote:
Though the most successful founders are usually good people, they tend to have a piratical gleam in their eye. They're not Goody Two-Shoes type good. Morally, they care about getting the big questions right, but not about observing proprieties. That's why I'd use the word naughty rather than evil. They delight in breaking rules, but not rules that matter. This quality may be redundant though; it may be implied by imagination.
Sam Altman of Loopt is one of the most successful alumni, so we asked him what question we could put on the Y Combinator application that would help us discover more people like him. He said to ask about a time when they'd hacked something to their advantage—hacked in the sense of beating the system, not breaking into computers. It has become one of the questions we pay most attention to when judging applications.
Or, to pick one of countless examples from Google, in order to reduce travel costs at Google, Google engineers implemented a system where they computed some kind of baseline "expected cost for flights, and then gave people a credit for taking flights that came in under the baseline costs that could be used to upgrade future flights and travel accommodations. This was a nice experience for employees compared to what stodgier companies were doing in terms of expense limits and Google engineers were proud of creating a system that made things better for everyone, which was one kind of hacking the system. The next level of hacking the system was when some employees optimized their flights and even set up trips to locations that were highly optimizable (many engineers would consider this a fun challenge, a variant of classic dynamic programming problems that are given in interviews, etc.), allowing them to upgrade to first class flights and the nicest hotels.
When I've talked about this with people in management in traditional industries, they've frequently been horrified and can't believe that these employees weren't censured or even fired for cheating the system. But when I was at Google, people generally found this to be admirable, as it exemplified the hacker spirit.
We can see, from the history of antitrust in tech going back at least two decades, that courts, regulators, and legislators have not been prepared for the vigor, speed, and delight with which tech companies hack the system.
And there's precedent for bringing in tech folks to work on the other side of the table. For example, this was done in the big Microsoft antitrust case. But there are incentive issues that make this difficult at every level that stem from, among other things, the sheer amount of money that tech companies are willing to pay out. If I think about tech folks I know who are very good at the kind of hacking the system described here, the ones who want to be employed at big companies frequently make seven figures (or more) annually, a sum not likely to be rivaled by an individual consulting contract with the DoJ or FTC. If we look at the example of Microsoft again, the tech group that was involved was managed by Ron Schnell, who was taking a break from working after his third exit, but people like that are relatively few and far between. Of course there are people who don't want to work at big companies for a variety of reasons, often moral reasons or a dislike of big company corporate politics, but most people I know who fit that description haven't spent enough time at big companies to really understand the mechanics of how big companies operate and are the wrong people for this job even if they're great engineers and great hackers.
At an antitrust conference a while back, a speaker noted that the mixing and collaboration between the legal and economics communities was a great boon for antitrust work. Notably absent from the speech as well as the conference were practitioners from industry. The conference had the feel of an academic conference, so you might see CS academics at the conference some day, but even if that were to happen, many of the policy-level discussions are ones that are outside the area of interest of CS academics. For example, one of the arguments from the BE memo that we noted as implausible was the way they used MAU to basically argue that switching costs were low. That's something outside the area of research of almost every CS academic, so even if the conference were to expand and bring in folks who work closely with tech, the natural attendees would still not be the right people to weigh in on the topic when it comes to the plausibility of nitty gritty details.
Besides the aforementioned impact on policy discussions, the lack of collaboration with tech folks also meant that, when people spoke about the motives of actors, they would often make assumptions that were unwarranted. On one specific example of what someone might call a hack of the system, the speaker described an exec's reaction (high-fives, etc.), and inferred a contempt for lawmakers and the law that was not in evidence. It's possible the exec in question does, in fact, have a contempt and disdain for lawmakers and the law, but that celebration is exactly what you might've seen after someone at Google figured out how to get upgraded to first class "for free" on almost all their flights by hacking the system at Google, which wouldn't indicate contempt or disdain at all.
Coming back to the incentive problem, it goes beyond getting people who understand tech on the other side of the table in antitrust discussions. If you ask Capitol Hill staffers who were around at the time, the general belief is that the primary factor that scuttled the FTC investigation was Google's lobbying, and of course Google and other large tech companies spend more on lobbying than entities that are interested in increased antitrust scrutiny.
And in the civil service, if we look at the lead of the BC investigation and the first author on the BC memo, they're now Director and Associate General Counsel of Competition and Regulatory Affairs at Facebook. I don't know them, so I can't speak to their motivations, but if I were offered as much money as I expect they make to work on antitrust and other regulatory issues at Facebook, I'd probably take the offer. Even putting aside the pay, if I was a strong believer in the goals of increased antitrust enforcement, that would still be a very compelling offer. Working for the FTC, maybe you lead another investigation where you write a memo that's much stronger than the opposition memo, which doesn't matter when a big tech company pours more lobbying money into D.C. and the investigation is closed. Or maybe your investigation leads to an outcome like the EU investigation that led to a "choice screen" that was too little and far too late. Or maybe it leads to something like the Android Play Store untying case where, seven years after the investigation was started, an enterprising Google employee figures out a "hack" that makes the consent decree useless in about five minutes. At least inside Facebook, you can nudge the company towards what you think is right and have some impact on how Facebook treats consumers and competitors.
Looking at it from the standpoint of people in tech (as opposed to people working in antitrust), in my extended social circles, it's common to hear people say "I'd never work at company X for moral reasons". That's a fine position to take but, almost everyone I know who does this ends up working at a much smaller company that has almost no impact on the world. If you want to take a moral stand, you're more likely to make a difference by working from the inside or finding a smaller direct competitor and helping it become more successful.
Thanks to Laurence Tratt, Yossi Kreinin, Justin Hong, kouhai@treehouse.systems, Sophia Wisdom, @cursv@ioc.exchange, @quanticle@mastodon.social, and Misha Yagudin for comments/corrections/discussion
Appendix: non-statements
This is analogous to the "non-goals" section of a technical design doc, but weaker, in that a non-goal in a design doc is often a positive statement that implies something that couldn't be implied from reading the doc, whereas the non-goal statements themselves don't add any informatio
Antitrust action against Google should have been pursued in 2012
Not that anyone should care what my opinion is, but if you'd asked me at the time if antitrust action should be pursued, I would've said "probably not". The case for antitrust action seems stronger now and the case against seems weaker, but you could still mount a fairly strong argument against antitrust action today.
Even if you believe that, ceteris paribus, antitrust action would've been good for consumers and the "very good case" outcome in "what might've happened" would occur if antitrust action were pursued, it's still not obvious that Google and other tech companies are the right target as opposed to (just for example) Visa and Mastercard's dominance of payments, hospital mergers leading to increased concentration that's had negative impacts on both consumers and workers, Ticketmaster's dominance, etc.. Or perhaps you think the government should focus on areas where regulation specifically protects firms, such as in shipping (which is except from the Sherman Act) or car dealerships (which have special protections in the law in many U.S. states that prevent direct sales and compel car companies to abide by their demands in certain ways), etc.
Weaker or stronger antitrust measures should be taken today
I don't think I've spent enough time reading up on the legal, political, historical, and philosophical background to have an opinion on what should be done, but I know enough about tech to point out a few errors that I've seen and to call out common themes in these errors.
BC Staff Memo
By "Barbara R. Blank, Gustav P. Chiarello, Melissa Westman-Cherry, Matthew Accornero, Jennifer Nagle, Anticompetitive Practices Division; James Rhilinger, Healthcare Division; James Frost, Office of Policy and Coordination; Priya B. Viswanath, Office of the Director; Stuart Hirschfeld, Danica Noble, Northwest Region; Thomas Dahdouh, Western Region-San Francisco, Attorneys; Daniel Gross, Robert Hilliard, Catherine McNally, Cristobal Ramon, Sarah Sajewski, Brian Stone, Honors Paralegals; Stephanie Langley, Investigator"
Dated August 8, 2012
Executive Summary
Google is dominant search engine and seller of search ads
This memo addresses 4 of 5 areas with anticompetitive conduct; mobile is in a supplemental memo
Google has monopoly power in the U.S. in Horizontal Search; Search Advertising; and Syndicated Search and Search Advertising
On the question of whether Google has unlawfully preferenced its own content while demoting rivals, we do not recommend the FTC proceed; it's a close call and case law is not favorable to anticompetitive product design and Google's efficiency justifications are strong and at there's some benefit to users
On whether Google has unlawfully scraped content from vertical rivals to improve their own vertical products, recommending condemning as a conditional refusal to deal under Section 2
Prior voluntary dealing was mutually beneficial
Threats to remove rival content from general search designed to coerce rivals into allowing Google to user their content for Google's vertical product
Natural and probable effect is to diminish incentives of vertical website R&D
On anticompetitive contractual restrictions on automated cross-management of ad campaigns, restrictions should be condemned under Section 2
They limit ability of advertisers to make use of their own data, reducing innovation and increasing transaction costs for advertisers and third-party businesses
Also degrade the quality of Google's rivals in search and search advertising
Google's efficiency justifications appears to be pretextual
On anticompetitive exclusionary agreements with websites for syndicated search and search ads, Google should be condemned under Section 2
Only modest anticompetitive effects on publishers, but deny scale to competitors, competitively significant to main rival (Bing) as well as significant barrier to entry in longer term
Google's efficiency justifications are, on balance, non-persuasive
Possible remedies
Scraping
Could be required to provide an opt-out for snippets (reviews, ratings) from Google's vertical properties while retaining snippets in web search and/or Universal Search on main search results page
Could be required to limit use of content indexed from web search results
Campaign management restrictions
Could be required to remove problematic contractual restrictions from license agreements
Exclusionary syndication agreements
Could be enjoined from entering into exclusive search agreements with search syndication partners and required to loosen restrictions surrounding syndication partners' use of rival search ads
There are a number of risks to case, not named in summary except that Google can argue that Microsoft's most efficient distribution channel is bing.com and that any scale MS might gain will be immaterial to Bing's competitive position
Staff concludes Google's conduct has resulted and will result in real harm to consumer, innovation in online search and ads.
I. HISTORY OF THE INVESTIGATION AND RELATED PROCEEDINGS
A. FTC INVESTIGATION
Compulsory process approved on June 03 2011
Received over 2M docs (9.5M pages) "and have reviewed many thousands of those documents"
Reviewed documents procured to DoJ in Google-Yahoo (2008) and ITA (2010) investigations and documents produced in response to European Commission and U.S. State investigations
Interviewed dozens of parties including vertical competitors in travel, local, finance, and retail; U.. advertisers and ad agencies; Google U.S. syndication and distribution partners; mobile device manufacturers and wireless carriers
17 investigational hearings of Google execs & employees
B. EUROPEAN COMMISSION INVESTIGATION
Parallel investigation since November 2010
May 21, 2012: Commissioner Joaquin Almunia issued letter signaling EC's possible intent to issue Statement of Objections for abuse of dominance in violation of Article 102 of EC Treaty
Concerns
"favourable treatment of its own vertical search services as compared to those of its competitors in its natural search results"
"practice of copying third party content" to supplement own vertical content
"exclusivity agreements with publishers for the provision of search advertising intermediation services"
"restrictions with regard to the portability and cross-platform management of online advertising campaigns"
offered opportunity to resolve concerns prior to issuance of SO by producing description of solutions
Google denied infringement of EU law, but proposed several commitments to address stated concerns
FTC staff coordinated with EC staff
C. MULTI-STATE INVESTIGATION
Texas investigating since June 2010, leader of multi-state working group
FTC working closely with states
D. PRIVATE LITIGATION
Several private lawsuits related to issues in our investigation; all dismissed
Two categories, manipulation of search rankings and increases in minimum prices for AdWords search ads
Kinderstart.com LLC v. Google, Inc.,1 ¹¹ and SearchKing, Inc. v. Google Tech., Inc., plaintiffs alleged that Google unfairly demoted their results
SearchKing court ruled that Google's rankings are constitutionally protected opinion; even malicious manipulation of rankings would not expose Google to tort liability
Kinderstart court rejected Google search being an essential facility for vertical websites
In AdsWords cases, plaintiffs argue that Google increased minimum bids for keywords they'd purchases, making those keywords effectively unavailable, depriving plaintiff website of traffic
TradeComet.com, LLC v. Google, Inc. dismissed for improper venue and Google, Inc. v. myTriggers.com, Inc. dismissed for failing to describe harm to competition has a whole
both dismissed with little discussion of merits
Person V. Google, Inc.: Judge Fogel of the Northern District of California criticized plaintiff's market definition, finding no basis for distinguishing "search advertising market" from larger market for internet advertising
II. STATEMENT OF FACTS
A. THE PARTIES
1. Google
Products include "horizontal" search engine and integrated "vertical" websites that focus on specific areas (product or shopping comparisons, maps, finance, books, video), search advertising via AdWords, search and search advertising syndication through AdSense, computer and software applications such as Google Toolbar, Gmail, Chrome, also have Android for mobile and applications for mobile devices and recently acquired Motorola Mobility
32k people, $38B annual revenue
2. General search competitors
a. Microsoft
MSN search released in 1998, rebranded Bing in 2009. Filed complaints against Google in 2011 with FTC and EC
b. Yahoo
Partnership with Bing since 2010; Bing provides search results and parties jointly operate a search ad network
3. Major Vertical Competition
In general, these companies complain that Google's practice of preferencing its own vertical results has negatively impacted ability to compete for users and advertisers
Amazon
Product search directly competes with Google Product Search
eBay
product search competes with Google Product Search
NexTag
shopping comparison website that competes with Google Product Search
Foundem
UK product comparison website that competes with Google Product Search
Complaint to EC, among others, prompted EC to open its investigation into Google's web search practices
First vertical website to publicly accuse Google of preferencing its own vertical content over competitors on Google's search page
Expedia
competes against Google's fledgling Google Flight Search
TripAdvisor
TripAdvisor competes with Google Local (formerly Google Places)
has complained that Google has appropriated / scraped its user-generated reviews, placing them on Google's own local property
Yelp
has complained that Google has appropriated / scraped its user-generated reviews, placing them on Google's own local property
Facebook
Competes with Google's recently introduced Google Plus
has complained that Google's preferencing of Google Plus results over Facebook results is negatively impacting ability to compete for users
B. INDUSTRY BACKGROUND
1. General Search
[nice description of search engines for lay people omitted]
2. Online Advertising
Google's core business is ads; 96% of its nearly $38B in revenue was from ad sales
[lots of explanations of ad industry for lay people, mostly omitted]
Reasons advertisers have shifted business to web include high degree of tracking possible and quantifiable, superior, ROI
Search ads make up most of online ad spend, primarily because advertisers believe search ads provided best precision in IDing customers, measurability, and the highest ROI
Online advertising continues to evolve, with new offerings that aren't traditional display or search ads, such as contextual ads, re-targeted behavioral ads, and social media ads
these new ad products don't account for a significant portion of online ads today and, with the exception of social media ads, appear to have only limited potential for growth [Surely video is pretty big now, especially if you include "sponsorships" and not just ads inserted by the platform?]
E.g., if you go "AOL or Ask.com", you can do a search which is powered by a search Provider, like Google
Publisher gets to keep user on own platform, search provider gets search volume and can monetize traffic
End-user doesn't pay; publisher pays Google either on cost-per-user-query basis or by accepting search ads and spitting revenues from search ads run on publisher's site. Revenue sharing agreement often called "traffic acquisition cost" (TAC)
Publishers can get search ads without offering search (AdSense) and vice versa
4. Mobile Search
Focus of search has been moving from desktop to "rapid emerging — and lucrative — frontier of mobile"
Android at forefront; has surpassed iPhone in U.S. market share
Mobile creates opportunities for location-based search ads; even more precise intent targeting than desktop search ads
Google and others have signed distribution agreements with device makers and wireless carriers, so user-purchased devices usually come pre-installed with search and other apps
C. THE SIGNIFICANCE OF SCALE IN INTERNET SEARCH
Scale (user queries and ad volume) important to competitive dynamics
1. Search Query Volume
Microsoft claims it needs higher query volume to improve Bing
Logs of queries can be used to improve tail queries
Suggestions, instant search, spelling correction
Trend identification, fresh news stories
Click data important for evaluating search quality
Udi Manber (former Google chief of search quality) testimony: "The ranking itself is affected by the click data. If we discover that, for a particular query, hypothetically, 80 percent of people click on Result No. 2 and only 10 percent click on Result No. 1, after a while we figure out, well, probably Result 2 is the one people want. So we'll switch it."
Testimony from Eric Schmidt and Sergey Brin confirms click data important and provides feedback on quality of search results
Scale / volume allows more experiments
Larry and Sergei's annual letter in 2005 notes importance of experiments, running multiple simultaneous experiments
More scale allows for more experiments as well as for experiments to complete more quickly
Susan Athey (Microsoft chief economist) says Microsoft search quality team is greatly hampered by insufficient search volume to run experiments
2009 comment from Udi Manber: "The bottom line is this. If Microsoft had the same traffic we have their quality will improve *significantly*, and if we had the same traffic they have, ours will drop significantly. That's a fact"
2. Advertising Volume
Microsoft claims they need more ad volume to improve relevance and quality of ads
More ads means more choices over what ads to serve to use, better matched ads / higher conversion rates
Also means more queries
Also has similar feedback loop to search
Increase volume of advertisers increases competitiveness for ad properties, gives more revenue to search engine
Allows search engine to amortize costs, re-invest in R&D, provide better advertiser coverage, revenue through revenue-sharing agreements to syndication partners (website publishers). Greater revenue to partners attracts more publishers and more advertisers
3. Scale Curve
Google acknowledges the important of scale (outside of the scope of this particular discussion)
Google documents replete with references to "virtuous cycle" among users, advertisers, and publishers
Testimony from Google execs confirms this
But Google argues scale no longer matters at Google's scale or Microsoft's scale, that additional scale at Microsoft's scale would not "significantly improve" Microsoft search quality
Susan Athey argues that relative scale, Bing being 1/5th the size of Google, matters, not absolute size
Microsoft claims that 5% to 10% increase in query volume would be "very meaningful", notes that gaining access to Yahoo queries and ad volume in 2010 was significant for search quality and monetization
Claim that Yahoo query data increased click through rate for "auto suggest" from 44% to 61% [the timeframe here is July 2010 to September 2011 — too bad they didn't provide an A/B test here, since this more than 1 year timeframe allows for many other changes to impact the suggest feature as well; did that ship a major change here without A/B testing it? That seems odd]
Microsoft also claims search quality improvements due to experiment volume enabled by extra query volume
D. GOOGLE'S SUSPECT CONDUCT
Five main areas of staff investigation of alleged anticompetitive conduct:
1. Google's Preferencing of Google Vertical Properties Within Its Search Engine Results Page ("SERP")
Allegation is that Google's conduct is anticompetitive because "it forecloses alternative search platforms that might operate to constraint Google's dominance in search and search advertising"
" Although it is a close call, we do not recommend that the Commission issue a complaint against Google for this conduct."
a. Overview of Changes to Google's SERP
Google makes changes to UI and algorithms, sometimes without user testing
sometimes with testing with launch review process, typically including:
"the sandbox", internal testing by engineers
"SxS", side-by-side testing by external raters who compare existing results to proposed results
Testing on a small percent of live traffic
"launch report" for Launch Committee
Google claims to have run 8000 SxS tests and 2500 "live" click tests in 2010, with 500 changes launched
"Google's stated goal is to make its ranking algorithms better in order to provide the user with the best experience possible."
b. Google's Development and Introduction of Vertical Properties
Google vertical properties launched in stages, initially around 2001
Google News, Froogle (shopping), Image Search, and Groups
Google has separate indexes for each vertical
Around 2005 ,Google realized that vertical search engines, i.e., aggregators in some categories were a "threat" to dominance in web search, feared that these could cause shift in some searches away from Google
From GOOG-Texas-1325832-33 (2010): "Vertical search is of tremendous strategic importance to Google. Otherwise the risk is that Google is the go-to place for finding information only in the cases where there is sufficiently low monetization potential that no niche vertical search competitor has filled the space with a better alternative."
2008 presentation titled "Online Advertising Challenges: Rise of the Aggregators":
"Issue 1. Consumers migrating to MoneySupermarket. Driver: General search engines not solving consumer queries as well as specialized vertical search Consequence: Increasing proportion of visitors going directly to MoneySupermarket. Google Implication: Loss of query volumes."
Issue 2: "MoneySupermarket has better advertiser proposition. Driver: MoneySupermarket offers cheaper, lower risk (CPA-based) leads to advertisers. Google Implication: Advertiser pull: Direct advertisers switch spend to MoneySupermarket/other channels"
In response to this threat, Google invested in existing verticals (shopping, local) and invested in new verticals (mortgages, offers, hotel search, flight search)
c. The Evolution of Display of Google's Vertical Properties on the SERP
Google initially had tabs that let users search within verticals
In 2003, Marissa Mayer started developing "Universal Search" (launched in 2007), to put this content directly on Google's SERP. Mayer wrote:
"Universal Search is an effort to redesign the user interface of the main Google.com results page SO that Google deliver[s] the most relevant information to the user on Google.com no matter what corpus that information comes from. This design is motivated by the fact that very few users are motivated to click on our tabs, SO they often miss relevant results in the other corpora."
Prior to Universal Search launch, Google used "OneBoxes", which put vertical content above Google's SERP
After launching Universal Search, vertical results could go anywhere
d. Google's Preferential Display of Google Vertical Properties on the SERP
Google used control over Google SERP both to improve UX for searches and to maximize benefit to its own vertical properties
Google wanted to maximize percentage of queries that had Universal Search results and drive traffic to Google properties
In 2008, goal to "[i]ncrease google.com product search inclusion to the level of google.com searches with 'product intent', while preserving clickthrough rate." (GOOG-Texas-0227159-66)
Q1 2008, goal of triggering Product Universal on 6% of English searches
Q2 2008, goal changed to top OneBox coverage of 50% with 10% CTR and "[i]ncrease coverage on head queries. For example, we should be triggering on at least 5 of the top 10 most popular queries on amazon.com at any given time, rather than only one."
"Larry thought product should get more exposure", GOOG-ITA-04-0004120-46 (2009)
Mandate from exec meeting to push product-related queries as quickly as possible
Launch Report for one algorithm change: 'To increase triggering on head queries, Google also implemented a change to trigger the Product Universal on google.com queries if they appeared often in the product vertical. "Using Exact Corpusboost to Trigger Product Onebox" compares queries on www.google.com with queries on Google Shopping, triggers the Product OneBox if the same query is often searched in Google Shopping, and automatically places the universal in position 4, regardless of the quality of the universal results or user "bias" for top placement of the box.'
"presentation stating that Google could take a number of steps to be "#1" in verticals, including "[e]ither [getting] high traffic from google.com, or [developing] a separate strong brand," and asking: "How do we link from Search to ensure strong traffic without harming user experience or AdWords proposition for advertisers?")", GOOGFOX-000082469 (2009)
Jon Hanke, head of Google Local, to Marissa Mayer: "long term, I think we need to commit to a more aggressive path w/ google where we can show non-webpage results on google outside of the universal 'box' most of us on geo think that we won't win unless we can inject a lot more of local directly into google results."
"Google's key strengths are: Google.com real estate for the ~70MM of product queries/day in US/UK/DE alone"
"I think the mandate has to come down that we want to win [in local] and we are willing to take some hits [i.e., trigger incorrectly sometimes]. I think a philosophical decision needs to get made that results that are not web search results and that displace web pages are "OK" on google.com and nothing to be ashamed of. That would open the door to place page or local entities as ranked results outside of some 'local universal' container. Arguably for many queriesall of the top 10 results should be local entities from our index with refinement options. The current mentality is that the google results page needs to be primarily about web pages, possibly with some other annotations if they are really, really good. That's the big weakness that bing is shooting at w/ the 'decision engine' pitch - not a sea of pointers to possible answers, but real answers right on the page. "
In spring 2008, Google estimated top placement of Product Universal would lead to loss of $154M/yr on product queries. Ads team requested reduction in triggering frequency and Product Universal team objected, "We face strong competition and must move quickly. Turning down onebox would hamper progress as follows - Ranking: Losing click data harms ranking; [t]riggering Losing CTR and google.com query distribution data triggering accuracy; [c]omprehensiveness: Losing traffic harms merchant growth and therefore comprehensiveness; [m]erchant cooperation: Losing traffic reduces effort merchants put into offer data, tax, & shipping; PR: Turning off onebox reduces Google's credibility in commerce; [u]ser awareness: Losing shopping-related UI on google.com reduces awareness of Google's shopping features."
"Google embellished its Universal Search results with photos and other eye-catching interfaces, recognizing that these design choices would help steer users to Google's vertical properties"
"Third party studies show the substantial difference in traffic with prominent, graphical user interfaces"; "These 'rich' user interfaces are not available to competing vertical websites"
Google search results near or at top of SERP, pushing other results down, resulting in reduced CTR to "natural search results"
Google did this without comparing quality of Google's vertical content to competitors or evaluating whether users prefer Google's vertical content to displaced results
click-through from eBay indicates that (Jan-Apr 2012), Google Product Search appeared in top 5 positon 64% of time when displayed and Google Product Search had lower CTR than web search in same position regardless of position [below is rank: natural result CTR / Google Shopping CTR / eBay CTR]
1: 38% / 21% / 31%
2: 21% / 14% / 20%
3: 16% / 12% / 18%
4: 13% / 9% / 11%
5: 10% / 8% / 10%
6: 8% / 6% / 9%
7: 7% / 5% / 9%
8: 6% / 2% / 7%
9: 6% / 3% / 6%
10 5% / 2% / 6%
11: 5% / 2% / 5%
12: 3% / 1% / 4%
Although Google tracks CTR and relies on CTR to improve web results, it hasn't relied on CTR to rank Universal Search results against other web search results
Marissa Mayer said Google didn't use CTR " because it would take too long to move up on the SERP on the basis of user click-through rate"
Instead, "Google used occurrence of competing vertical websites to automatically boost the ranking of its own vertical properties above that of competitors"
If comparison shopping site was relevant, Google would insert Google Product search above any rival
If local search like Yelp or CitySearch was relevant, Google automatically returned Google Local at top of SERP
Google launched commission-based verticals, mortgage, flights, offers, in ad space reserved exclusively for its own properties
In 2012, Google announced that google product search would transition to paid and Google would stop including product listings for merchants who don't pay to be listed
Google's dedicated ads don't competition with other ads via AdWords and automatically get the most effective ad spots, usually above natural search results
As with Google's Universal results, its own ads have a rich user interface not available to competitors which results in higher CTR
e. Google's Demotion of Competing Vertical Websites
"While Google embarked on a multi-year strategy of developing and showcasing its own vertical properties, Google simultaneously adopted a strategy of demoting, or refusing to display, links to certain vertical websites in highly commercial categories"
"Google has identified comparison shopping websites as undesirable to users, and has developed several algorithms to demote these websites on its SERP. Through an algorithm launched in 2007, Google demoted all comparison shopping websites beyond the first two on its SERP"
"Google's own vertical properties (inserted into Google's SERP via Universal Search) have not been subject to the same demotion algorithms, even though they might otherwise meet the criteria for demotion."
Google has acknowledged that its own vertical sites meet the exact criteria for demotion
Additionally, Google's web spam team originally refused to add Froogle to search results because "[o]ur algorithms specifically look for pages like these to either demote or remove from the index."
Google's web spam team also refused to add Google's local property
f. Effects of Google's SERP Changes on Vertical Rivals
"Google's prominent placement and display of its Universal Search properties, combined with the demotion of certain vertical competitors in Google's natural search results, has resulted in significant loss of traffic to many competing vertical websites"
"Google's internal data confirms the impact, showing that Google anticipated significant traffic loss to certain categories of vertical websites when it implemented many of the algorithmic changes described above"
"While Google's changes to its SERP led to a significant decrease in traffic for the websites of many vertical competitors, Google's prominent showcasing of its vertical properties led to gains in user share for its own properties"
"For example, Google's inclusion of Google Product Search as a Universal Search result took Google Product Search from a rank of seventh in page views in July 2007 to the number one rank by July 2008. Google product search leadership acknowledged that '[t]he majority of that growth has been driven through product search universal.'"
"Beyond the direct impact on traffic to Google and its rivals, Google's changes to its SERP have led to reduced investment and innovation in vertical search markets. For example, as a result of the rise of Google Product Search (and simultaneous fall of rival comparison shopping websites), NexTag has taken steps to reduce its investment in this area. Google's more recent launch of its flight search product has also caused NexTag to cease development of an 'innovative and competitive travel service.'"
2. Google's "Scraping" of Rivals' Vertical Content
"Staff has investigated whether Google has "scraped" - or appropriated - the content of rival vertical websites in order to improve its own vertical properties SO as to maintain, preserve, or enhance Google's monopoly power in the markets for search and search advertising. We recommend that the Commission issue a complaint against Google for this conduct."
In addition to developing its own vertical properties, Google scraped content from existing vertical websites (e.g., Yelp, TripAdvisor, Amazon) in order to improve its own vertical listings, "e.g., GOOG-Texas-1380771-73 (2009), at 71-72 (discussing importance of Google Places carrying better review content from Yelp)."
a. The "Local" Story
"Some local information providers, such as Yelp, TripAdvisor, and CitySearch, disapprove of the ways in which Google has made use of their content"
"Google recognized that review content, in particular, was "critical to winning in local search," but that Google had an 'unhealthy dependency' on Yelp for much of its review content. Google feared that its heavy reliance on Yelp content, along with Yelp's success in certain categories and geographies, could lead Yelp and other local information websites to siphon users' local queries away from Google"
"concern that Yelp could become competing local search platforms" (Goog-Texas-0975467-97)
Google Local execs tried to convince Google to acquire Yelp, but failed
Yelp, on finding that Google was going to use reviews on its own property, discontinued its feed and asked for Yelp content to be removed from Google Local
"after offering its own review site for more than two years, Google recognized that it had failed to develop a community of users - and thus, the critical mass of user reviews - that it needed to sustain its local product.", which led to failed attempt to buy Yelp
To address this problem, Google added Google Places results on SERP: "The listing for each business that came up as a search result linked the user directly to Google's Places page, with a label indicating that hundreds of reviews for the business were available on the Places page (but with no links to the actual sources of those reviews).On the Places Page itself, Google provided an entire paragraph of each copied review (although not the complete review), followed by a link to the source of the review, such as Yelp (which it crawled for reviews) and TripAdvisor (which was providing a feed)."
Yelp noticed this in July 2010, that Google was featuring Yelp's content without a license and protested to Google. TripAdvisor chose not to renew license with Google after finding same
Google implemented new policy that would ban properties from Google search if they didn't allow their content to be used in Google Places
"GOOG-Texas-1041511-12 (2010), at 12 ("remove blacklist of yelp [reviews] from Web-extracted Reviews once provider based UI live"); GOOG-Texas-1417391-403 (2010), at 394 ("stating that Google should wait to publish a blog post on the new UI until the change to "unblacklist Yelp" is "live")."
Along with this policy, launched new reviews product and seeded it reviews from 3rd party websites without attribution
Yelp, CitySearch, and TripAdvisor all complained and were all told that they could only remove their content if they were fully removed from search results. "This was not technically necessary - it was just a policy decision by Google."
Yelp sent Google a C&D
Google claimed it was technically infeasible to remove Yelp content from Google Places without also banning Yelp from search result
Google later did this, making it clear that the claim that it was technically infeasible was false
Google still maintained that it would be technically infeasible to remove Yelp from Google Places without removing it from "local merge" interface on SERP. Staff believes this assertion is false as well because Google maintains numerous "blacklists" that prevent content from being shown in specific locations
Mayer later admitted during hearing that the infeasible claim was false and that Google feared consequences of allowing websites to opt out of Google Places while staying in "local merge"
"Yelp contends that Google's continued refusal to link to Yelp on Google's 'local merge' interface on the main SERP is simply retaliation for Yelp seeking removal from Google Places."
"Publicly, Google framed its changes to Google Local as a redesign to move toward the provision of more original content, and thereby, to remove all third-party content and review counts from Google Local, as well as from the prominent "local merge" Universal Search interface on the main SERP. But the more likely explanation is that, by July 2011,Google had already collected sufficient reviews by bootstrapping its review collection on the display of other websites' reviews. It no longer needed to display third-party reviews, particularly while under investigation for this precise conduct."
b. The "Shopping" Story
[full notes omitted; story is similar to above, but with Amazon; similar claims of impossibility of removing from some places and not others; Amazon wanted Google to stop using Amazon star ratings, which Google claimed was impossible without blacklisting Amazon from all of web search, etc.; there's also a parallel story about Froogle's failure and Google's actions after that]
c. Effects of Google's "Scraping" on Vertical Rivals
"Because Google scraped content from these vertical websites over an extended period of time, it is difficult to point to declines in traffic that are specifically attributable to Google's conduct. However, the natural and probable effect of Google's conduct is to diminish the incentives of companies like Yelp, TripAdvisor, CitySearch, and Amazon to invest in, and to develop, new and innovative content, as the companies cannot fully capture the benefits of their innovations"
3. Google's API Restrictions
"Staff has investigated whether Google's restrictions on the automated cross-management of advertising campaigns has unlawfully contributed to the maintenance, preservation, or enhancement of Google's monopoly power in the markets for search and search advertising. Microsoft alleges that these restrictions are anticompetitive because they prevent Google's competitors from achieving efficient scale in search and search advertising. We recommend that the Commission issue a complaint against Google for this conduct."
a. Overview of the AdWords Platform
To set up AdWords, advertisers prepare bids. Can have thousands or hundreds of thousands of keywords.
E.g., DirectTV might bid on "television", "TV", and "satellite" plus specific TV show names, such as "Friday Night Lights", as well as misspellings
Bids can be calibrated by time and location
Advertisers then prepare ads (called "creatives") and match with various groups of keywords
Advertisers get data from AdWords, can evaluate effectiveness and modify bids, add/drop keywords, modify creative
This is called "optimization" when done manually; expensive and time-intensive
Initially two ways to access AdWords system, AdWords Front End and AdWords Editor
Editor is a program. Allows advertisers to download campaign information from Google, make bulk changes offline, then upload changes back to AdWords
Advertisers would make so many changes that system's capacity would be exceeded, causing outages
In 2004, Google added AdWords API to address problems
[description of what an API is omitted]
b. The Restrictive Conditions
AdWords API terms and conditions non-negotiable, apply to all users
One restriction prevents advertisers from using 3rd party tool or have 3rd party use a tool to copy data from AdWords API into ad campaign on another search network
Another, can't use 3rd party tool or have 3rd party use a tool to comingle AdWords campaign data with data from another search engine
The two conditions above will be referred to as "the restrictive conditions"
"These restrictions essentially prevent any third-party tool developer or advertising agency from creating a tool that provides a single user interface for multiple advertising campaigns. Such tools would facilitate cross-platform advertising."
"However, the restrictions do not apply to advertisers themselves, which means that very large advertisers, such as.Amazon and eBay, can develop - and have developed - their own multi-homing tools that simultaneously manage campaigns across platforms"
"The advertisers affected are those whose campaign volumes are large enough to benefit from using the AdWords API, but too small to justify devoting the necessary resources to develop in-house the software and expertise to manage multiple search network ad campaigns."
c. Effects of the Restrictive Conditions
i. Effects on Advertisers and Search Engine Marketers ("SEMs")
Prevents development of tools that would allow advertisers from managing ad campaigns on multiple search ad networks simultaneously
Google routinely audits API clients for compliance
Google has required SEMs to remove functionality, "e.g., GOOGEC-0180810-14 (2010) (Trada); GOOGEC-0180815-16 (2010) (MediaPlex); GOOGEC-0181055-58 (2010) (CoreMetrics); GOOGEC-0181083-87 (2010) (Keybroker); GOOGEC-0182218-330 (2008) (Marin Software). 251 Acquisio IR (Sep. 12, 2011); Efficient Frontier IR (Mar. 5, 2012)"
Other SEMs have stated they would develop this functionality without restrictions
"Google anticipated that the restrictive conditions would eliminate SEM incentives to innovate.", "GOOGKAMA-000004815 (2004), at 2."
"Many advertisers have said they would be interested in buying a tool that had multi-homing functionality. Such functionality would be attractive to advertisers because it would reduce the costs of managing multiple ad campaigns, giving advertisers access to additional advertising opportunities on multiple search advertising networks with minimal additional investment of time. The advertisers who would benefit from such a tool appear to be the medium-sized advertisers, whose advertising budgets are too small to justify hiring a full service agency, but large enough to justify paying for such a tool to help increase their advertising opportunities on multiple search networks."
ii. Effects on Competitors
Removing restrictions would increase ad spend on networks that compete with Google
Data on advertiser multi-homing show some effects of restrictive conditions. Nearly all the largest advertisers multi-home, but percentage declines as spend decreases
Advertisers would also multi-home with more intensity
Microsoft claims that multi-homing advertisers optimize their Google campaigns almost-daily, Microsoft campaigns less frequently, weekly or bi-weekly
Without incremental transaction costs, "all rational advertisers would multi-home"
Staff interviewed randomly selected small advertisers. Interviews "strongly supported" thesis that advertises would multi-home if cross-platform optimization tool were available
Some advertisers don't advertise on Bing due to lack of tool, the ones that do do less optimization
d. Internal Google Discussions Regarding the Restrictions
Internal discussions support the above
PM wrote the following in 2007, endorsed by director of PM Richard Holden:
"If we offer cross-network SEM in [Europe], we will give a significant boost to our competitors. Most advertisers that I have talked to in [Europe] don't bother running campaigns on [Microsoft] or Yahoo because the additional overhead needed to manage these other networks outweighs the small amount of additional traffic. For this reason, [Microsoft] and Yahoo still have a fraction of the advertisers that we have in [Europe], and they still have lower average CPAs [cost per acquisition]"
"This last point is significant. The success of Google's AdWords auctions has served to raise the costs of advertising on Google. With more advertisers entering the AdWords auctions, the prices it takes to win those auctions have naturally risen. As a result, the costs per acquisition on Google have risen relative to the costs per acquisition on Bing and Yahoo!. Despite these higher costs, as this document notes, advertisers are not switching to Bing and Yahoo! because, for many of them, the transactional costs are too great."
In Dec 2008, Google team led by Richard Holden evaluated possibility of relaxing or removing restrictive conditions and consulted with Google chief economist Hal Varian. Some of Holden's observations:
Advertisers seek out SEMs and agencies for cross-network management technology and services;
The restrictive conditions make the market more inefficient;
Removing the restrictive conditions would "open up the market" and give Google the opportunity to compete with a best-in-class SEM tool with "a streamlined workflow";
Removing the restrictive conditions would allow SEMs to improve their tools as well;
While there is a risk of additional spend going to competing search networks, it is unlikely that Google would be seriously harmed because "advertisers are going where the users are," i.e., to Google
"internally, Google recognized that removing the restrictions would create a more efficient market, but acknowledged a concern that doing so might diminish Google's grip on advertisers."
"Nonetheless, following up on that meeting, Google began evaluating ways to improve the DART Search program. DART Search was a cross-network campaign management tool owned by DoubleClick, which Google acquired in 2008. Google engineers were looking at improving the DART Search product, but had to confront limitations imposed by the restrictive conditions. During his investigational hearing, Richard Holden steadfastly denied any linkage between the need to relax the restrictive conditions and the plans to improve DART Search. ²⁷⁴ However, a series of documents - documents authored by Holden - explicitly link the two ideas."
Dec 2008 Holden to SVP of ad products, Susan Wojcicki and others met.
Holden wrote: "[O]ne debate we are having is whether we should eliminate our API T&Cs requirement that AW [AdWords] features not be co-mingled with competitor network features in SEM cross-network tools like DART Search. We are advocating that we eliminate this requirement and that we build a much more streamlined and efficient DART Search offering and let SEM tool provider competitors do the same. There was some debate about this, but we concluded that it is better for customers and the industry as a whole to make things more efficient and we will maximize our opportunity by moving quickly and providing the most robust offering"
Feb 2009, Holden wrote exec summary for DART, suggested Google ""alter the AdWords Ts&Cs to be less restrictive and produce the leading cross-network toolset that increases advertiser/agency efficiency." to "[r]educe friction in the search ads sales and management process and grow the industry faster"
Larry Page rejected this. Afterwards, Holden wrote "We've heard that and we will focus on building the product to be industry-leading and will evaluate it with him when it is done and then discuss co-mingling and enabling all to do it."
Sep 2009, API PM raised possibility of eliminating restrictive conditions to help DART. Comment from Holden:
"I think the core issue on which I'd like to get Susan's take is whether she sees a high risk of existing spend being channeled to MS/Yahoo! due to a more lenient official policy on campaign cloning. Then, weigh that risk against the benefits: enabling DART Search to compete better against non-compliant SEM tools, more industry goodwill, easier compliance enforcement. Does that seem like the right high level message?"
"The documents make clear that Google was weighing the efficiency of relaxing the restrictions against the potential cost to Google in market power"
"At a January 2010 meeting, Larry Page decided against removing or relaxing the restrictive conditions. However, there is no record of the rationale for that decision or what weight was given to the concern that relaxing the restrictive conditions might result in spend being channeled to Google's competitors. Larry Page has not testified. Holden testified that he did not recall the discussion. The participants at the meeting did not take notes "for obvious reasons." Nonetheless, the documents paint a clear picture: Google rejected relaxing the API restrictions, and at least part of the reason for this was fear of diverting advertising spend to Microsoft."
4. Google's Exclusive and Restrictive Syndication Agreements
"Staff has investigated whether Google has entered into exclusive or highly restrictive agreements with website publishers that have served to maintain, preserve, or enhance Google's monopoly power in the markets for search, search advertising, or search and search advertising syndication (or "search intermediation"). We recommend that the Commission issue a complaint against Google for this conduct."
a. Publishers and Market Structure
Buyers of search and search ad syndication are website publishers
Largest sites account for vast majority of syndicated search traffic and volume
Biggest customers are e-commerce retailers (e.g., Amazon and eBay), traditional retailers with websites (e.g., Wal-Mart, Target, Best Buy), and ISPs which operate their own portals
Below this group, companies with significant query volume, including vertical e-commerce sites such as Kayak, smaller retailers and ISPs such as EarthLink; all of these are < 1% of Google's total AdSense query volume
Below, publisher size rapidly drops off to < 0.1% of Google's query volume
Payment publisher receives a function of
volume of clicks on syndicated ad
"CPC", or cost-per-click advertiser willing to pay for each click
revenue sharing percentage
rate of user clicks and CPC aggregated to form "monetization rate"
b. Development of the Market for Search Syndication
First AdSense for Search (AFS) agreements with AOL and EarthLink in 2002
Goal then was to grow nascent industry of syndicated search ads
At the time, Google was bidding against incumbent Overture (later acquired by Yahoo) for exclusive agreements with syndication partners
Google's early deals favored publishers
To establish a presence, Google offered up-front financial guarantees to publishers
c. Specifics of Google's Syndication Agreements
"Today, the typical AdSense agreement contains terms and conditions that describe how and when Google will deliver search, search advertising, and other (contextual or domain related) advertising services."
Two main categories are AFS (search) and AFC (content). Staff investigation focused on AFS
For AFS, two types of agreements. GSAs (Google Service Agreements) negotiated with large partners and standard online contracts, which are non-negotiable and non-exclusive
Bulk of AFS partners are on standard online agreements, but those are a small fraction of revenue
Bulk of revenue comes from GSAs with Google's 10 largest partners (almost 80% of query volume in 2011). All GSAs have some form of exclusivity or "preferred placement" for Google
"Google's exclusive AFS agreements effectively prohibit the use of non-Google search and search advertising within the sites and pages designated in the agreement. Some exclusive agreements cover all properties held by a publisher globally; other agreements provide for a property-by-property (or market-by-market) assignment"
By 2008, Google began to migrate away from exclusivity to "preferred placement". Google must display minimum of 3 ads or number of any competitor (whichever is greater), in an unbroken block, with "preferred placement" (in the most prominent position on publisher's website)
Google had preferred placement restrictions in GSAs and standard online agreement. Google maintains it was not aware of this provision in standard online agreement until investigational hearing of Google VP for search services, Joan Braddi, where staff questioned Braddi
See Letter from Scott Sher, Wilson Sonsini, to Barbara Blank (May 25, 2012) (explaining that, as of the date of the letter, Google was removing the preferred placement clause from the Online Terms and Conditions, and offering no further explanation of this decision)
d. Effects of Exclusivity and Preferred Placement
Staff interviewed large and small customers for search and search advertising syndication. Key findings:
i. Common Publisher Responses
Universal agreement that Bing's search and search advertising markedly inferior, not competitive across-the-board
Amazon reports that Bing monetizes at half the rate of Google
business.com told staff that Google would have to cut revenue share from 64.5% to 30% and Microsoft would have to provide 90% share because Microsoft's platform has such low monetization
Customers "generally confirmed" Microsoft's claim that Bing's search syndication is inferior in part because Microsoft's network is smaller than Google's
With a larger ad base, Google more likely to have relevant, high-quality, ad for any given query, which improves monetization rate
A small publisher said, essentially, the only publishers exclusively using Bing are ones who've been banned from Google's service
We know from other interviews this is an exaggeration, but it captures the general tenor of comments about Microsoft
Publishers reported Microsoft not aggressively trying to win their business
Microsoft exec acknowledge that Bing needs a larger portfolio of advertisers, has been focused there over winning new syndication business
Common theme from many publishers is that search is a relatively minor part of their business and not a strategic focus. For example, Wal-Mart operates website as extension to retail and Best Buy's main goal of website is to provide presale info
Most publishers hadn't seriously considered Bing due to poor monetization
Amazon, which does use Bing and Google ads, uses a single syndication provider on a page to avoid showing the user the same ad multiple times on the same page; mixing and matching arrangement generally considered difficult by publishers
Starting in 2008, Google systematically tried to lower revenue share for AdSense partners
E.g., "Our general philosophy with renewals has been to reduce TAC across the board", "2009 Traffic Acquisition Cost (TAC) was down 3 percentage points from 2008 attributable to the application of standardized revenue share guidelines for renewals and new partnerships...", etc.
Google reduced payments (TAC) to AFS partners from 80.4% to 74% between Q1 2009 and Q1 2010
No publisher viewed reduction as large enough to justify shifting to Bing or serving more display ads instead of search ads
ii. Publishers' Views of Exclusivity Provisions
Some large publishers reported exclusive contracts and some didn't
Most publishers with exclusivity provisions didn't complain about them
A small number of technically sophisticated publishers were deeply concerned by exclusivity
These customers viewed search and search advertising as a significant part of business, have the sophistication to integrate multiple suppliers into on-line properties
eBay: largest search and search ads partner, 27% of U.S. syndicated search queries in 2011
Contract requires preferential treatment for AdSense ads, which eBay characterizes as equivalent to exclusivity
eBay wanted this removed in last negotiation, but assented to not removing it in return for not having revenue share cut while most other publishers had revenue share cut
eBay's testing indicates that Bing is competitive in some sectors, e.g., tech ads; they believe they could make more money with multiple search providers
NexTag: In 2015, Google's 15th largest AFS customer
Had exclusivity, was able to remove it in 2010, but NexTag considers restrictions "essentially the same thing as exclusivity"; "NexTag reports that moving away from explicit exclusivity even to this kind of de facto exclusivity required substantial, difficult negotiations with Google"
Has had discussions with Yahoo and Bing about using their products "on a filler basis", but unable to do so due to Google contract restrictions
business.com: B2B lead generation / vertical site; much smaller than above. Barely in top 60 of AdSense query volume
Exclusive agreement with Google
Would test Bing and Yahoo without exclusive agreement
Agreement also restricts how business.com can design pages
Loosening exclusivity would improve business.com revenue and allow for new features that make the site more accessible and user-friendly
Amazon: 2nd largest AFS customer after eBay; $175M from search syndication, $169M from Google AdSense
Amazon uses other providers despite their poor monetization due to concerns about having a single supplier; because Amazon operates on thin margins, $175M is a material source of profit
Amazon concerned it will be forced to sign an exclusive agreement in next negotiation
During last negotiation, Amazon wanted 5-year deal, Google would only give 1-year extension unless Amazon agreed to send Google 90% of search queries (Amazon refused to agree to this formally, although they do this)
IAC: umbrella company operating ask.com, Newsweek, CityGrid, Urbanspoon, and other websites
Agreement is exclusive on a per-property basis
IAC concerned about exclusivity. CityGrid wanted mix-and-match options, but couldn't compete with Google's syndication network, forced to opt into IAC's exclusive agreement; CityGrid wants to use other networks (including its own), but can't under agreement with Google
IAC concerned about lack of competition in search and search advertising syndication
Execute who expressed above concerns left, new executive didn't see a possibility of splitting or moving traffic
"The departure of the key executive with the closest knowledge of the issues and the most detailed concerns suggests we may have significant issues obtaining clear, unambiguous testimony from IAC that reflects their earlier expressed concerns."
iii.Effects on Competitors
Microsoft asserts even 5%-10% increase in query volume "very meaningful" and Google's exclusive and restrictive agreements deny Microsoft incremental scale to be more efficient competitor
Speciality search ad platforms also impacted; IAC sought to build platform for local search advertising, but Google's exclusivity provisions "make it less likely that small local competitors like IAC's nascent offering can viably emerge."
III. LEGAL ANALYSIS
"A monopolization claim under Section 2 of the Sherman Act, 15 U.S.C. § 2, has two elements: (i) the 'possession of monopoly power in the relevant market' and (ii) the 'willful acquisition or maintenance of that power as distinguished from growth or development as a consequence of a superior product, business acumen, or historic accident.'"
"An attempted monopolization claim requires a showing that (i) 'the defendant has engaged in predatory or anticompetitive conduct' with (ii) 'a specific intent to monopolize' and (iii) a dangerous probability of achieving or maintaining monopoly power."
A. GOOGLE HAS MONOPOLY POWER IN RELEVANT MARKETS
"'A firm is a monopolist if it can profitably raise prices substantially above the competitive level. [M]onopoly power may be inferred from a firm's possession of a dominant share of a relevant market that is protected by entry barriers.' Google has monopoly power in one or more properly defined markets."
1. Relevant Markets and Market Shares
"A properly defined antitrust market consists of 'any grouping of sales whose sellers, if unified by a hypothetical cartel or merger, could profitably raise prices significantly above the competitive level.'"
"Typically, a court examines 'such practical indicia as industry or public recognition of the submarket as a separate economic entity, the product's peculiar characteristics and uses, unique production facilities, distinct customers, distinct prices, sensitivity to price changes, and specialized vendors.'"
"Staff has identified three relevant antitrust markets."
a. Horizontal Search
Vertical search engines not a viable substitute to horizontal search; formidable barriers to expanding into horizontal search
Vertical search properties could pick up query volume in response to SSNIP (small, but significant non-transitory increase in price) in horizontal search, potentially displacing horizontal search providers
Google views these with concern, has aggressively moved to build its own vertical offerings
No mechanism for vertical search properties to broadly discipline a monopolist in horizontal search
Web search queries monetized through search ads, ads sold by keyword which have independent demand functions. So, at best, monopolist might be inhibited from SSNIP on a narrow set of keywords with strong vertical competition. But for billions of queries with no strong vertical, nothing constrains monopolist from SSNIP
Where vertical websites exist, still hard to compete; comprehensive coverage of all areas seems to be important driver of demand, even to websites focusing on specific topics. Eric Schmidt noted this:
"So if you, for example, are an academic researcher and you use Google 30 times for your academics, then perhaps you'll want to buy a camera... So long as the product is very, very, very, very good, people will keep coming back... The general product then creates the brand, creates demand and so forth. Then occasionally, these ads get clicked on"
Schmidt's testimony corroborated by several vertical search firms, who note that they're dependent on horizontal search providers for traffic because vertical search users often start with Google, Bing, or Yahoo
When asked about competitors in search, Eric Schmidt mentioned zero vertical properties
Google internal documents monitor Bing and Yahoo and compare quality. Sergei Brin testified that he wasn't aware of any such regular comparison against vertical competitors
Relevant geo for web search limited to U.S. here; search engines return results relevant to users in country they're serving, so U.S. users unlikely to view foreign-specialized search engines as viable substitute
Although Google has managed to cross borders, other major international search engines (Baidu, Yandex) have filed to do this
Google dominant for "general search" in U.S.; 66.7% share according to ComScore, and also provides results to ask.com and AOL, another 4.6%
Yahoo 15%, Bing 14%
Google's market share above generally accepted floor for monopolization; defendants with share in this range have been found to have monopoly power
b. Search Advertising
Search ads likely a properly defined market
Search ads distinguishable from other online ads, such as, display ads, contextual ads, behavioral ads, social media ads due to "inherent scale, targetability, and control"
Google: "[t]hey are such different products that you do not measure them against one another and the technology behind the products is different"
Evidence suggests search and display ads are complements, not substitutes
"Google has observed steep click declines when advertisers have attempted to shift budget to display advertising"
Chevrolet suspended search ads for 2 weeks and relied on display ads alone; lost 30% of clicks
New ad offerings don't fit into traditional search or display categories: contextual, re-targeted display (or behavioral), social media
Only search ads allow advertisers to show ad based on when user is expressing an interest in the moment the ad is shown; numerous advertisers confirmed this point
Search ads convert at much higher rate due to this advantage
Numerous advertisers report they wouldn't shift ad spend away from search ads if prices increased more than SSNIP. Living Social would need 100% price increase before shifting ads (a minority of advertisers reported they would move ad dollars from search in response to SSNIP)
Google internal documents and testimony confirm lack of viable substitute for search. AdWords VP Nick Fox and chief economist Hal Varian have stated that search ad spend doesn't come at expense of other ad dollars, Eric Schmidt has testified multiple times that search ads are the most effective ad tool, has best ROI
Google, through AdWords, has 76% to 80% of the market according to industry-wide trackers (rival Bing-Yahoo has 12% to 16%)
[It doesn't seem wrong to say that search ads are a market and that Google dominates that market, but the primacy of search ads seems overstated here? Social media ads, just becoming important at the time, ended up becoming very important, and of course video as well]
c. Syndicated Search and Search Advertising ("Search Intermediation")
Syndicated search and search advertising ("search intermediation") are likely a properly defined product market
Horizontal search providers sell ("syndicate") services to other websites
Search engine can also return search ads to the website; search engine and website share revenue
Consumers are websites that want search; sellers are horizontal search providers, Google, Bing, Yahoo
Publishers of various sizes consistent on cross-elasticity of demand; report that search ad syndication monetizes better than display advertising or other content
No publisher told us that modest (5% to 10%) increase in price for search and search ad syndication would favor other forms of advertising or web content
Google's successful efforts to systematically reduce TAC support this, are a natural experiment to determine likely response to SSNIP
Google, via AdSense, is dominant provider of search and search ad syndication; 75% of market according to ComScore (Microsoft and Yahoo combine for 22%)
2. Substantial Barriers to Entry Exist
"Developing and maintaining a competitively viable search or search ad platform requires substantial investment in specialized knowledge, technology, infrastructure, and time. These markets are also characterized by significant scale effects"
a. Technology and Specialization
[no notes, extremely obvious to anyone technical who's familiar with the area]
b. Substantial Upfront Investment
Enormous investments required. For example in 2011, Google spent $5B on R&D. And in 2010, MS spent more than $4.5B developing algorithms and building physical capacity for Bing
c. Scale Effects
More usage leads to better algorithms and greater accuracy w.r.t. what consumers want
Also leads to greater number of advertisers
Greater number of advertisers and consumers leads to better ad serving accuracy, better monetization of ads, leads to better monetization for search engine, advertisers, and syndication partners
Cyclical effect, "virtuous cycle"
According to Microsoft, greatest barrier is obtaining sufficient scale. Losing $2B/yr trying to compete with Google, and Bing is only competing horizontal search platform to Google
d. Reputation, Brand Loyalty, and the "Halo Effect"
[no notes]
e. Exclusive and Restrictive Agreements -
"Google's exclusive and restrictive agreements pose yet another barrier to entry, as many potential syndication partners with a high volume of customers are locked into agreements with Google."
B. GOOGLE HAS ENGAGED IN EXCLUSIONARY CONDUCT
"Conduct may be judged exclusionary when it tends to exclude competitors 'on some basis other than efficiency,' i.e., when it 'tends to impair the opportunities of rivals' but 'either does not further competition on the merits or does SO in an unnecessarily restrictive way.' In order for conduct to be condemned as 'exclusionary,' Staff must show that Google's conduct likely impairs the ability of its rivals to compete effectively, and thus to constrain Google's exercise of monopoly power"
1. Google's Preferencing of Google Vertical Properties Within Its SERP
"Although we believe that this is a close question, we conclude that Google's preferencing conduct does not violate Section 2."
a. Google's Product Design Impedes Vertical Competitors
"As a general rule, courts are properly very skeptical about claims that competition has been harmed by a dominant firm's product design changes. Judicial deference to product innovation, however, does not mean that a monopolist's product design decisions are per se lawful", United States v. Microsoft
We evaluate, through Microsoft lens of monopoly maintenance, whether Google took these actions to impede a nascent threat to Google's monopoly power
"Google's internal documents explicitly reflect - and testimony from Google executives confirms - a concern that Google was at risk of losing, in particular, highly profitable queries to vertical websites"
VP of product management Nicholas Fox:
"[Google's] inability to serve this segment [of vertical lead generation] well today is negatively impacting our business. Query growth among high monetizing queries (>$120 RPM) has declined to ~0% in the UK. US isn't far behind (~6%). There's evidence (e.g., UK Finance) that we're losing share to aggregators"
Threat to Google isn't vertical websites, displacing Google, but that they'll undercut Google's power over the most lucrative segments of search and search ads portfolio
Additionally, vertical websites could help erode barriers to growth for general search competitors
b. Google's SERP Changes Have Resulted In Anticompetitive Effects
Google expanding its own offerings while demoting rival offerings caused significant drops in traffic to rivals, confirmed by Google's internal data
Google's prominent placement of its own Universal Search properties led to gains in share of its own properties
"For example, Google's inclusion of Google Product Search as a Universal Search result turned a property that the Google product team could not even get indexed by Google's web search results into the number one viewed comparison shopping website on Google"
c. Google's Justifications for the Conduct
"Product design change is an area of conduct where courts do not tend to strictly scrutinize asserted procompetitive justifications. In any event, Google's procompetitive justifications are compelling."
Google argues design changes to SERP have improved product, provide consumers with "better" results
Google notes that path toward Universal Search and OneBox predates concern about vertical threat
Google justifies preferential treatment of Universal Search by asserting "apples and oranges" problem prevents Google from doing head-to-head comparison of its property vs. competing verticals, verticals and web results ranked with different criteria. This seems to be correct.
Microsoft says Bing uses a single signal, click-through-rate, that can be compared across Universal Search content and web search results
Google claims that its Universal Search results are more helpful than than "blue links" to other comparison shopping websites
Google claims that showing 3rd party data would create technical and latency issues
" The evidence shows that it would be technologically feasible to serve up third-party results in Google's Universal Search results. Indeed, Bing does this today with its flight vertical, serving up Kayak results and Google itself originally considered third-party OneBoxes"
Google defends "demotion" of competing vertical content, "arguing that Google's algorithms are designed solely with the goal of improving a user's search experience"
"one aspect of Google's demotions that especially troubles Staff - and is not addressed by the above justification - is the fact that Google routinely, and prominently, displays its own vertical properties, while simultaneously demoting properties that are identical to its own, but for the fact that the latter are competing vertical websites", See Brin Tr. 79:16-81:24 (acknowledging the similarities between Google Product Search and its competitors); Fox Tr. 204:6-204:20 (acknowledging the similarities between Google Product Search and its competitors).
d. Google's Additional Legal Defenses
"Google has argued - successfully in several litigations - that it owes no duty to assist in the promotion of a rival's website or search platform, and that it owes no duty to promote a rival's product offering over its own product offerings"
"one reading of Trinko and subsequent cases is that Google is privileged in blocking rivals from its search platform unless its conduct falls into in one of several specific exceptions referenced in Trinko"
"Alternatively, one may argue that Trinko should not be read so broadly as to overrule swathes of antitrust doctrine."
"Google has long argued that its general search results are opinions that are protected speech under the First Amendment, and that such speech should not be subject to government regulation"; staff believes this is overbroad
"the evidence paints a complex portrait of a company working toward an overall goal of maintaining its market share by providing the best user experience, while simultaneously engaging in tactics that resulted in harm to many vertical competitors, and likely helped to entrench Google's monopoly power over search and search advertising"
"The determination that Google's conduct is anticompetitive, and deserving of condemnation, would require an extensive balancing of these factors, a task that courts have been unwilling - in similar circumstances - to perform under Section 2. Thus, although it is a close question, Staff does not recommend that the Commission move forward on this cause of action."
2. Google's "Scraping" of Rivals' Vertical Content
"We conclude that this conduct violates Section 2 and Section 5."
a. Google's "Scraping" Constitutes a Conditional Refusal to Deal or Unfair Method Of Competition
Scraping and threats of refusal to deal with some competitors can be condemned as conditional refusal to deal under Section 2
Post-Trinko, identification of circumstances ("[u]nder certain circumstances, a refusal to cooperate with rivals can constitute anticompetitive conduct and violate § 2") "subject of much debate"
Aspen Skiing Co. v. Aspen Highlands Skiing Corp: defendant (owner of 3 of 4 ski areas in Aspen) canceled all-ski area ticket with plaintiff (owner of 4th ski area in Aspen)
After demand increasing share of profit, defendant canceled ticket and rejected "increasingly desperate measures" to recreate joint ticket, even rejected plaintiff's offer to buy tickets at retail price
Supreme court upheld jury's finding of liability; Trinko court: "unilateral termination of a voluntary (and thus presumably profitable) course of dealing suggested a willingness to forsake short-term profits to achieve an anticompetitive end. Similarly, the defendant's unwillingness to renew the ticket even if compensated at retail price revealed a distinctly anticompetitive bent"
Appellate courts have focused on Trinko's reference to "unilateral termination of a voluntary course of dealing", e.g., in American Central Eastern Texas Gas Co.v. Duke Energy Fuels LLC, Fifth Circuit upheld determination that defendant natural gas processor's refusal to contract with competitor for additional capacity was unlawful
Plaintiff contracted with defendant for processing capacity; after two years, defendant proposed terms it "knew were unrealistic or completely unviable ... in order to exclude [the plaintiff] from competition with [the defendant] in the gas processing market."
Case here is analogous to Aspen Skiing and Duke Energy [a lot of detail not written down in notes here]
b. Google's "Scraping" Has Resulted In Anticompetitive Effects
Scraping has lessened the incentives of competing websites like Yelp, TripAdvisor, CitySearch, and Amazon to innovate, diminishes incentives of other vertical websites to develop new products
entrepreneurs more reluctant to develop new sites, investors more reluctant to sponsor development when Google can use its monopoly power to appropriate content it deems lucrative
c. Google's "Scraping" Is Not Justified By Efficiencies
"Marissa Mayer and Sameer Samat testified that was extraordinarily difficult for Google, as a technical matter, to remove sites like Yelp from Google Local without also removing them from web search results"
"Google's almost immediate compliance after Yelp sent a formal 'cease and desist' letter to Google, however, suggests that the "technical" hurdles were not a significant factor in Google's refusal to comply with repeated requests to remove competitor content from Google Local"
Partners can opt out of inclusion with Google's vertical news offering, Google News
"Similarly, Google's almost immediate removal of Amazon product reviews from Google Product Search indicates that technical barriers were quickly surmounted when Google desired to accommodate a partner."
"In sum, the evidence shows that Google used its monopoly position in search to scrape content from rivals and to improve its own complementary vertical offerings, to the detriment of those rivals, and without a countervailing efficiency justification. Google's scraping conduct has helped it to maintain, preserve, and enhance Google's monopoly position in the markets for search and search advertising. Accordingly, we believe that this conduct should be condemned by the Commission."
3. Google's API Restrictions
"We conclude that Google's API restrictions violate Section 2."
AdWords API procompetitive development
But restrictive conditions in API usage agreement anticompetitive, without offsetting procompetitive benefits
"Should the restrictive conditions be found to be unreasonable restraints of trade, they could be removed today instantly, with no adverse effect on the functioning of the API. Any additional engineering required to make the advertiser data interoperable with other search networks would be supplied by other market participants. Notably, because Google would not be required to give its competitors access to the AdWords API, there is no concern about whether Google has a duty to deal with its competitors"
a. The Restrictive Conditions Are Unreasonable
Restrictive conditions limit ability of advertisers to use their own data, prevent the development and sale of 3rd party tools and services that would allow automated campaign management across multiple search networks
"Even Google is constrained by these restrictions, having had to forgo improving its DART Search tool to offer such capabilities, despite internal estimates that such functionality would benefit Google and advertisers alike"
Restrictive conditions have no procompetitive virtues, anticompetitive effects are substantial
b. The Restrictive Conditions Have Resulted In Anticompetitive Effects
Restrictive conditions reduce innovation, increase transaction costs, degrade quality of Google's rivals in search and search advertising
Several SEMs forced to remove campaign cloning functionality by Google; Google's restrictive conditions stopped cross-network campaign management tool market segment in its infancy
Restrictive conditions increase transaction costs for all advertisers other than those large enough to make internal investments to develop their own tools [doesn't it also, in some amortized fashion, increase transaction costs for companies that can build their own tools?]
Result is that advertisers spend less on non-dominant search networks, reducing quality of ads on non-dominant search networks
c. The Restrictive Conditions Are Not Justified By Efficiencies
Concern about "misaligned incentives" is Google's only justification for restrictive conditions; concern is that SEMs and agencies would adopt a "lowest common denominator" approach and degrade AdWords campaign performance
"The evidence shows that this justification is unsubstantiated and is likely a pretext"
"In brief, these third parties incentives are highly aligned with Google's interests, precisely the opposite of what Google contends."
Google unable to identify an examples of ill effects from misaligned incentives
Terms and Conditions already have conditions for minimum functionality that prevents lowest common denominator concern from materializing
Documents suggest restrictive conditions were not about "misaligned incentives":
"Sergey [Brin] and Larry [Page] are big proponents of a protectionist strategy that prevents third party developers from building offerings which promote the consolidated management of [keywords] on Google and Overture (and whomever else)."
In a 2004 doc, API product manager was looking for "specific points on how we can prevent a new entrant (MSN Ad Network) from benefitting from a common 3rd party platform that is cross-network."
In a related presentation, Google's lists as a concern, "other competitors are buoyed by lowered barriers to entry"; options to prevent this were "applications must have Google-centric UI functions and branding" and "disallow cross-network compatible applications from using API"
4. Google's Exclusive and Restrictive Syndication Agreements
"Staff has investigated whether Google has entered into anticompetitive, exclusionary agreements with websites for syndicated search and search advertising services (AdSense agreements) that serve to maintain, preserve, or enhance Google's monopoly power in the markets for search, search advertising, or search and search advertising syndication (search intermediation). We conclude that these agreements violate Section 2."
a. Google's Agreements Foreclose a Substantial Portion of the Relevant Market
"Exclusive deals by a monopolist harm competition by foreclosing rivals from needed relationships with distributors, suppliers, or end users. For example, in Microsoft, then-defendant Microsoft's exclusive agreements with original equipment manufacturers and software vendors were deemed anticompetitive where they were found to prevent third parties from installing rival browser Netscape, thus foreclosing Netscape from the most efficient distribution channel, and helping Microsoft to preserve its operating system monopoly. The fact that an agreement is not explicitly exclusive does not preclude a finding of liability."
[notes on legal background of computing foreclosure percentage omitted]
Staff relied on ComScore dataset to compute foreclosure; Microsoft and and Yahoo's syndicated query volume is higher than in ComScore, resulting in lower foreclosure number. "We are trying to get to the bottom of this discrepancy now. However, based on our broader understanding of the market, we believe that the ComScore set more accurately reflects the relative query shares of each party." [I don't see why staff should believe that ComScore is more accurate than Microsoft's numbers — I would guess the opposite]
[more notes on foreclosure percentage omitted]
b. Google's Agreements Have Resulted In Anticompetitive Effects
Once foreclosure is established as above "safe harbor" levels, need a qualitative, rule of reason analysis of market effects
Google's exclusive agreements impact immediate market for search and search syndication advertising and have broader effects in markets for search and search advertising
In search search ad syndication (search intermediation), exclusivity precludes some of the largest and most sophisticated publishers from using competing platforms. Publishers can't credibly threaten to shift some incremental business to other platforms to get price concessions from Google
Google's aggressive reduction of revenue shares to customers without significant resistance => agreements seem to be further entrenching Google's monopoly position
An objection to this could be that Google's business is because its product is superior
This argument rests on fallacious assumption that Bing's average monetization gap is consistent across the board
[section on CityGrid impact omitted; this section speaks to broader market effects]
Google insists that incremental traffic to Microsoft would be trivial; Microsoft indicates it would be "very meaningful"
Not enough evidence for definitive conclusion, but "internal Google documents suggest that Microsoft's view of things may be closer to the truth. — Google's interest in renewing deals in part to prevent MIcrosoft from gaining scale. Internal Google analysis of 2010 AOL renewal: "AOL holds marginal search share but represents scale gains for a Microsoft + Yahoo! partnership. AOL/Microsoft combination has modest impact on market dynamics, but material increase in scale of Microsoft's search & ads platform"
When informed that "Microsoft [is] aggressively wooing AOL with large guarantees,", a Google exec responded with: "I think the worse case scenario here is that AOL users get sent to Bing, so even if we make AOL a bit more competitive relative to Google, that seems preferable to growing Bing."
Google internal documents show they pursued AOL deal aggressively even though AOL represented "[a] low/no profit partnership for Google."
Evidence is that, in near-term, removing exclusivity would not have dramatic impact; largest and most sophisticated publishers would shift modest amounts of traffic to Bing
Most significant competitive benefits realized over longer period of time
"Removing exclusivity may open up additional opportunities for both established and nascent competitors, and those opportunities may spur more significant changes in the market dynamics as publishers have the opportunity to consider - and test - alternatives to Google's AdSense program."
c. Google's Agreements Are Not Justified By Efficiencies
Google has given three business justifications for exclusive and restrictive syndication agreements
Long-standing industry practice of exclusivity, dating from when publishers demanded large, guaranteed, revenue share payments regardless of performance
"guaranteed revenue shares are now virtually non-existent"
"Google is simply engaging in a vigorous competition with Microsoft for exclusive agreements"
"Google may argue that the fact that Microsoft is losing in a competitive bidding process (and indeed, not competing as vigorously as it might otherwise) is not a basis on which to condemn Google. However, Google has effectively created the rules of today's game, and Microsoft's substantial monetization disadvantage puts it in a poor competition position to compete on an all-or-nothing basis."
"user confusion" — "Google claims that it does not want users to confuse a competitor's poor advertisements with its own higher quality advertisements"
"This argument suffers both from the fact that it is highly unlikely that users care about the source of the ad, as well as the fact that, if users did care, less restrictive alternatives are clearly available. Google has not explained why alternatives such as labeling competitor advertisements as originating from the competitor are unavailing here."
"Google's actions demonstrate that "user confusion" is not a significant concern. In 2008 Google attempted to enter into a non-exclusive agreement with Yahoo! to supplement Yahoo!'s search advertising platform. Under the proposed agreement, Yahoo! would return its own search advertising, but supplement its inventory with Google search advertisements when Yahoo! did not have sufficient inventory.58, Additionally, Google has recently eliminated its "preferred placement" restriction for its online partners."
Rule of reasons analysis shows strong evidence of market protected by high entry barriers
Despite limitations to evidence, market is inarguably not robustly competitive today
Google has been unilaterally reducing revenue share with apparent impunity
IV. POTENTIAL REMEDIES
A. Scraping
At least two possible remedies
Opt-out to remove snippets of content from Google's vertical properties, while retaining web search results and/or in Universal Search results on main SERP
Google could be required to limit use of content it indexes for web search (could only use content in returning the property in its search results, but not for determining its own product or local rankings) unless given explicit permission
B. API Restrictions
Require Google to remove problematic contractual restrictions; no technical fixes necessary
SEMs report that technology for cross-compatibility already exists, will quickly flourish if unhindered by Google's contractual constraints
C. Exclusive and Restrictive Syndication Agreements
Most appropriate remedy is to enjoin Google form entering exclusive agreement with search syndication partners, and to require Google to loosen restrictions surrounding AdSense partners' use of rival search ads
V. LITIGATION RISKS
Google does not charge customers, and they are not locked into Google
Universal Search has resulted in substantial benefit to users
Google's organization and aggregation of content adds value to product for customers
Largest advertisers advertise on both Google AdWords and Microsoft AdCenter
Most efficient channel through which Bing can gain scale is Bing.com
Microsoft has the resources to purchase distribution where it seems greatest value
Most website publishers appy with AdSense
VI. CONCLUSION
"Staff concludes that Google's conduct has resulted - and will result - in real harm to consumers and to innovation in the online search and advertising markets. Google has strengthened its monopolies over search and search advertising through anticompetitive means, and has forestalled competitors' and would-be competitors' ability to challenge those monopolies, and this will have lasting negative effects on consumer welfare"
"Google has unlawfully maintained its monopoly over general search and search advertising, in violation of Section 2, or otherwise engaged in unfair methods of competition, in violation of Section 5, by scraping content from rival vertical websites in order to improve its own product offerings."
"Google has unlawfully maintained its monopoly over general search, search advertising, and search syndication, in violation of Section 2, or otherwise engaged in unfair methods of competition, in violation of Section 5, by entering into exclusive and highly restrictive agreements with web publishers that prevent publishers from displaying competing search results or search advertisements."
"Google has unlawfully maintained its monopoly over general search and search advertising, in violation of Section 2, or otherwise engaged in unfair methods of competition, in violation of Section 5, by maintaining contractual restrictions that inhibit the cross-platform management of advertising campaigns."
"For the reasons set forth above, Staff recommends that the Commission issue the attached complaint."
Memo submitted by Barbara R. Blank, approved by Geoffrey M. Green and Malanie Sabo
FTC BE staff memo
"Bureau of Economics
August 8, 2012
From: Christopher Adams and John Yun, Economists"
Executive Summary
Anticompetitive investigation started June 2011
Staff presented theories and evidence February 2012
This memo offers our final recommendation
Four theories of harm
preferencing of search results by favoring own web properties over rivals
exclusive agreements with publishers and vendors, deprive rival platforms of users and advertisers
restrictions on porting advertiser data to rival platforms
misappropriating content from Yelp and TripAdvisor
"our guiding approach must be beyond collecting complaints and antidotes [presumably meant to be anecdotes?] from competitors who were negatively impacted from a firm's various business practices."
Market power in search advertising
Google has "significant' share, 65% of paid clicks and 53% of ad impressions among top 5 U.S. search engines
Market power may be mitigated by the fact that 80% use a search engine other than Google
Empirical evidence consistent with search and non-search ads being substitutes, and that Google considers vertical search to be competitors
Preferencing theory
Theory is that Google is blending its proprietary content with customary "blue links" and demoting competing sites
Google has limited ability to impose significant harm on vertical rivals because it accounts for 10% to 20% of traffic to them. Effect is very small and not statistically significant
[Funny that something so obviously wrong at the time and also seemingly wrong in retrospect was apparently taken seriously]
Universal Search was a procompetitive response to pressure from vertical sites and an improvement for users
Exclusive agreements theory
Access to a search engine's site (i.e., not dependent on 3rd party agreement) is most efficient and common distribution channel, which is not impeded by Google. Additionally, strong reasons to doubt that search toolbars and default status on browsers can be viewed as "exclusives" because users can easily switched (on desktop and mobile)
[statement implies another wrong model of what's happening here]
[Specifically on easy switching on mobile, there's Googe's actual blocking of changing the default search engine from Google to what the user wants, but we also know that a huge fraction of users basically don't understand what's happening and can't make an informed decision to switch — if this weren't the case, it wouldn't make sense for companies to bid so high for defaults, e.g. supposedly $26B/yr to obtain default search engine status on iOS; if users simply switch freely with, default status would be worth close to $0. Since this payment is, at the margin, pure profit and Apple's P/E ratio is 29.53 as of my typing this sentence, a quick and dirty estimate is that $776B of Apple's market cap is attributable to taking this payment vs. randomly selecting a default]
[In addition to explicit, measurable, coercion like the above, there were also things like Google pressuring Samsung into shutting down their Android Browser effort in 2012; although enforcing a search engine default on Android was probably not the primer driver on that or other similar pressure that Google applied, many of these sorts of things also had the impact of funneling users into Google on mobile; these economists seem like the incentive-based argument that users will use the best product, so the result we see in the market, but if that's the case, why do companies spend so much effort on ecosystem lock-in, including but not limited to supposedly paying $18B/yr to own the default setting in one browser? I guess the argument here is that companies are behaving completely irrationally in expending so much effort here, but consumers are behaving perfectly rationally and are fully informed and are not influenced by all of this spending at all?]
In search syndication, Microsoft and Yahoo have a combined greater share than Google's
No support for assertion that rivals' access to users has been impaired by Google. MS and Yahoo have had a steady 30% share for year; query volume has grown faster than Google since alliance was announced
[Another odd statement; at the time, observers didn't see Bing staying competitive without heavy subsidies from MS, and then MS predictably stopped subsidizing Bing as a big bet and its market share declined. Google's search market share is well above 90% and hasn't been below 90% since the BE memo was written; in the U.S., estimates put Google around 90% share, some a bit below and some a bit above, with low estimates at something like 87%. It's odd that someone could look at the situation at the time and not seeing that this was about to happen]
In December 2011, Microsoft had access to query volume equivalent to what Google had 2 years ago, thus difficult to infer that Microsoft is below some threshold of query volume
[this exact argument was addressed in the BC memo; the BE memo does not appear to refute the BC memo's argument]
[As with a number of the above arguments, this is a strange argument if you understand the dynamics of fast-growing tech companies. When you have rapidly growing companies in markets with network effects or scale effects, being the same absolute size as a competitor a number of years ago doesn't mean that you're in an ok position. We've seen this play out in a ton of markets and it's fundamental to why VCs shovel so much money at companies in promising markets — being a couple years behind often means you get crushed or, if you're lucky, end up as an also ran that's fighting an uphill battle against scale effects]
Characteristics of online search market not consistent with Google buying distribution agreements to raise input costs of rivals
Restrictions on porting advertiser data to AdWords API
Theory is that Google's terms and conditions for AdWords API anticompetitively disadvantages Microsoft's adCenter
Introduction of API with co-mingling restriction made users and Google better off and rivals's costs were unaffected. Any objection therefore implies that when Google introduced the API, it had an obligation to allow its rivals to benefit from increased functionality. Significant risks to long-term innovation incentives from imposing such an obligation [Huh, this seems very weird]
Advertisers responsible for overwhelming majority of search ad spend use both Google and Microsoft. Multi-homing advertisers of all sizes spend a significant share of budget on Microsoft [this exact objection is addressed in BC memo]
Evidence from SEMs and end-to-end advertisers suggest policy's impact on ad spend on Microsoft's platform is negligible [it's hard to know how seriously to take this considering the comments on Yelp, above — the model of how tech businesses work seems very wrong, which casts doubt on other conclusions that necessarily require having some kind of model of how this stuff works]
Scraping allegation is that Google has misappropriated content from Yelp and TripAdvisor
Have substantive concerns. Solution proposed in Annex 11
To be an antitrust violation, need strong evidence that it increased users on Google at expensive of Yelp or TripAdvisor or decreased incentives to innovate. No strong evidence of either [per above comments, this seems wrong]
Recommendation: recommend investigation be closed
1. Does Google possess monopoly power in the relevant antitrust market?
To be in violation of Section 2 of the Sherman Act, Google needs to be a monopoly or have substantial market power in a relevant market
Online search similar to any other advertising
Competition between platforms and advertisers depends on extent to which advertisers consider users on one platform to be substitutes for another
Google's market power depends on share of internet users
If advertisers can access Google's users at other search platforms, such as Yahoo, Bing, and Facebook, "Google's market power is a lot less"
Substantial evidence contradicting proposition that GOogle has substantial market power in search advertising
Google's share is large. In Feb 2012, 65% of paid search clicks of top 5 general search engines went through Google, up from 55% in Sep 2008; these figures show Google offers advertisers what they want
Advertisers want "eyeballs"
Users multi-home. About 80% of users use a platform other than Google in a given month, so advertisers can get the same eyeballs elsewhere
Advertiser can get in front of a user on a different query on Yahoo or another search engine
[this is also odd reasoning — if a user uses Google for searches by default, but occasionally stumbles across Yahoo or Bing, this doesn't meaningfully move the needle for an advertiser; the evidence here is comScore saying that 20% of users only use Google, 15% never use Google, and 65% use Google + another search engine; but it's generally accepted that comScore numbers are quite off. Shortly after the report was written, I looked at various companies that reported metrics (Alexa, etc.) and found them to be badly wrong; I don't think it would be easy to dig up the exact info I used at the time now, but on searching for "comscore search engine market accuracy", the first hit I got was someone explaining that while, today, comScore shows that Google has an implausibly low 67% market share, an analysis of traffic to sites this company has access to showed that Google much more plausibly drove 85% of clicks; it seems worth mentioning that comScore is often considered inaccurate]
Firm-level advertising between search ads and display ads is negatively correlated
[this seems plausible? The evidence in the BC memo for these being complements seemed like a stretch; maybe it's true, but the BE memo's position seems much more plausible]
No claim that these are the same market, but can't conclude that they're unrelated
Google competes with specialized search engines, similar to a supermarket competing with a convenience store [details on this analogy elided; this memo relies heavily on analogies that relate tech markets to various non-tech markets, some of which were also elided above]
For advertising on a search term like "Nikon 5100", Amazon may provide a differentiated but competing product
Google is leading seller of search, but this is mitigated by large proportion of users who also user other search engines, by substitution of display and search advertising, by competition in vertical search
Theory 1: The preferencing theory
2.1 Overview
Preferencing theory is that Google's blending of content such as shopping comparison results and local business listings with customary blue links disadvantages competing content sites, such as Nextag, eBay, Yelp, and TripAdvisor
2.2 Analysis
Blend has two effects, negatively impacting traffic to specialized vertical sites by pushing down sites and impacting Google's incentives to show competing vertical sites
Empirical questions
"To what extent does Google account for the traffic to vertical sites?"
"To what extent do blends impact the likelihood of clicks to vertical sites?"
"To what extent do blends improve consumer value from the search results?"
2.3 Empirical evidence
Google search responsible for 10% of traffic to shopping comparison sites, 17.5% to local business search sites. "See Annex 4 for a complete discussion of our platform model"
[Annex 4", doesn't appear to be included; but, as discussed above, the authors' model of how traffic works seems to be wrong]
When blends appear, from Google's internal data, clicks to other shopping comparison sites drop by a large and statistically significant amount. For example, if a site had a pre-blend CTR of 9%, post-blend CTR would be 5.3%, but a blend isn't always presented
For local, pre-blend CTR of 6% would be reduced to 5.4%; local blends have smaller impact than shopping
"above result for shopping comparison sites is not the same as finding that overall traffic from Google to shopping sites declined due to universal search. As we describe below, if blends represent a quality improvement, this will increase demand and drive greater query volume on Google, which will boost traffic to all sites."
All links are substitutes, so we can infer that if user user clicks on ads less, they prefer the content and the user is getting more value. Overall results indicate that blends significantly increase consumer value
[this seems obviously wrong unless the blend is presented with the same visual impact, weight, and position, as normal results, which isn't the case at all — I don't disagree that the blend is probably better for consumers, but this methodology seems like a classic misuse of data to prove a point]
2.4 Documentary evidence
Since the 90s, general search engines have incorporated vertical blends
All major search engines use blends
2.5 Summary of the preferencing theory
Google not significant enough source of traffic to forclose its vertical rivals [as discussed above, the model for this statement is wrong]
Theory 2: Exclusionary practices in search distribution
3.1 Overview
Theory is that Google is engaging in exclusionary practices in order to deprive Microsoft of economies of scale
Foundational issues
Are Google's distribution agreements substantially impairing opportunity of rivals to compete for users?
What's the empirical evidence users are being excluded and denied?
What's the evidence that Microsoft is at a disadvantage in terms of scale?
3.2 Are the various Google distribution agreements in fact exclusionary?
"Exclusionary agreements merit scrutiny when they materially reduce consumer choice and substantially impair the opportunities of rivals"
On desktop, users can access search engine directly, via web browser search box, or a search toolbar
73% of desktop search through direct navigation, all search engines have equal access to consumers in terms of direct access; "Consequently, Google has no ability to impair the opportunities of rivals in the most important and efficient desktop distribution channel."
[once again, this model seems wrong — if it wasn't wrong, companies wouldn't pay so much to become a search default, including shady stuff like Google paying shady badware installers to make Chrome / Google default on people's desktops. Another model is that if a user uses a search engine because it's a default, this changes a the probability that they'll use the search engine via "direct access"; compared to the BE staff model, it's overwhelmingly likely that this model is correct and the BE staff model is wrong]
Microsoft is search default on Internet Explorer and 70% of PCs sold
For syndication agreement, Google has a base template that contains premium placement provision. This is to achieve minimum level of remuneration in return for Google making its search available. Additionally, clause is often subject to negotiation and can be modified
[this negotiation thing is technically correct, but doesn't address the statement about this brought up in the BC memo; many, perhaps most, of the points in this memo have been refuted by the BC memo, and the strategy here seems to be to ignore the refutations without addressing them]
"By placing its entire site or suite of suites up for bid, publishers are able to bargain more effectively with search engines. This intensifies the ex ante competition for the contract and lowers publishers' costs. Consequently, eliminating the ability to negotiate a bundled discount, or exclusivity, based on site-wide coverage will result in higher prices to publishers." [this seems to contradict what we observe in practice?]
"This suggests that to the extent Google is depriving rivals such as Microsoft of scale economies, this is a result of 'competition on the merits'— much the same way as if Google had caused Microsoft to lose traffic because it developed a better product and offered it at a lower price."
Have Google's premium placement requirements effectively denied Microsoft access to publishers?
Can approach this by considering market share. Google 44%, including Aol and Ask. MS 31%, including Yahoo. Yahoo 25%. Combined, Yahoo and MS are at 56%. "Thus, combined, Microsoft and Yahoo's syndication shares are higher than their combined shares in a general search engine market" [as noted previously, these stats didn't seem correct at the time and have gotten predictably less directionally correct over time]
What would MS's volume be without Google's exclusionary restrictions
At most a 5% change because Google's product is so superior [this seems to ignore the primary component of this complaint, which is that there's a positive feedback cycle]
Search syndication agreements
Final major distribution channel is mobile search
U.S. marketshare: Android 47%, iOS 30%, RIM 16%, MS 5%
Android and iOS grew from 30% to 77% from December 2009 to December 2011, primarily due to decline of RIM, MS, and Palm
Mobile search is 8%. Thus, "small percentage of overall queries and and even smaller percentage of search ad revenues"
[The implication here appears to be that mobile is small and unimportant, which was obviously untrue at the time to any informed observer — I was at Google shortly after this was written and the change was made to go "mobile first" on basically everything because it was understood that mobile was the future; this involved a number of product changes that significantly degraded the experience on desktop in order to make the mobile experience better; this was generally considered not only a good decision, but the only remotely reasonable decision. Google was not alone in making this shift at the time. How economists studying this market didn't understand this after interviewing folks at Google and other tech companies is mysterious]
Switching cost on mobile implied to be very low, "a few taps" [as noted previously, the staggering amount of money spent on being a mobile default and Google's commit linked above indicate this is not true]
Even if switching costs were significant, there's no remedy here. "Too many choices lead to consumer confusion"
Repeat of point that barrier to switching is low because it's "a few taps"
"Google does not require Google to be the default search engine in order to license the Android OS" [seems technically correct, but misleading at best when taken as part of the broader argument here]
OEMs choose Google search as default for market-based reasons and not because their choice is restricted [this doesn't address the commit linked above that actually prevents users from switching the default away from Google; I wonder what the rebuttal to that would be, perhaps also that user choice is bad and confusing to users?]
Opportunities available to Microsoft are larger than indicated by marketshare
Summary
Marketshare could change quickly; two years ago, Apple and Google only had 30% share
Default of Google search not anticompetitive and mobile a small volume of queries, "although this is changing rapidly"
Basically no barrier to user switching, "a few taps and downloading other search apps can be achieved in a few seconds. These are trivial switching costs" [as noted above, this is obviously incorrect to anyone who understands mobile, especially the part about downloading an app not being a barrier; I continue to find it interesting that the economists used market-based reasoning when it supports the idea that the market is perfectly competitive, with no switching costs, etc., but decline to use market-based reasoning, such as noting the staggeringly high sums paid to set default search, when it supports the idea the that the the market is not a perfectly competitive market with no switching costs, etc.]
3.3 Are rival search engines being excluded from the market?
Prior section found that Google's distribution agreements don't impair opportunity of rivals to reach users. But could it have happened? We'll look at market shares and growth trends to determine
"We note that the evidence of Microsoft and Yahoo's share and growth cannot, even in theory, tell us whether Google's conduct has had a significant impact. Nonetheless, if we find that rival shares have grown or not diminished, this fact can be informative. Additionally, assuming that Microsoft would have grown dramatically in the counterfactual, despite the fact that Google itself is improving its product, requires a level of proof that must move beyond speculation." [as an extension of the above, the economists are happy to speculate or even 'move beyond speculation' when it comes to applying speculative reasoning on user switching costs, but apparently not when it comes to inferences that can be made about marketshare; why the drastic difference in the standard of proof?]
Microsoft and Yahoo's share shows no design of being excluded, steady 30% for 4 years [as noted in a previous section, the writing was on the wall for Bing and Yahoo at this time, but apparently this would "move beyond speculation" and is not noted here]
Since announcement of MS / Yahoo alliance, MS query volume as grown faster than Google [this is based on comScore qSerach data and the more detailed quoted claim is that MS Query volume increased 134% while Google volume increased 54%; as noted above, this seems like an inaccurate metric, so it's not clear why this would be used to support this point, and it's also misleading at best]
MS-Yahoo have the same number of search engine users as Google in a given month [again, as noted above, this appears to come from incorrect data and is also misleading at best because it counts a single use in a month as equivalent to using something many times a day]
3.4 Does Microsoft have sufficient scale to be competitive?
In a meeting with Susan Athey, Microsoft could not demonstrate that they had data definitively showing how the cost curve changes as click data changes, "thus, there is basis for suggesting Microsoft is below some threshold point" [the use of the phrase "threshold point" demonstrates either a use of sleight of hand or a lack of understanding of how it works; the BE memo seems to prefer the idea that it's about some threshold since this could be supported by the argument that, if such a threshold were to be demonstrated, Microsoft's growth would have or will carry it past the threshold, but it doesn't make any sense that there would a threshold; also, even if this were important, having a single meeting where Microsoft wasn't able to answer this immediately would be weak evidence]
[many more incorrect comments in the same vein as the above omitted for brevity]
"Finally, Microsoft's public statements are not consistent with statements made to antitrust regulators. Microsoft CEO Steve Ballmer stated in a press release announcing the search agreement with Yahoo: 'This agreement with Yahoo! will provide the scale we need to deliver even more rapid advances in relevancy and usefulness. Microsoft and Yahoo! know there's so much more that search could be. This agreement gives us the scale and resources to create the future of search."
[it's quite bizarre to use a press release, which are generally understood to be meaningless puff pieces, as evidence that a strongly supported claim isn't true; again, BE staff seem to be extremely selective about what evidence they look at to a degree that is striking; for example from conversations I had with credible, senior, engineers who worked on search at both Google and Bing, engineers who understand the domain would agree that having more search volume and more data is a major advantage; instead of using evidence like that, BE staff find a press release that, in the tradition of press releases, has some meaningless and incorrect bragging, and bring that in as evidence; why would they do this?]
[more examples of above incorrect reasoning, omitted for brevity]
3.5 Theory based on raising rivals' costs
Despite the above, it could be that distribution agreements deny rivals and data enough that "feedback effects" are triggered
Possible feedback effects
Scale effect: cost per unit of quality or ad matching decreases
Indirect network effect: more advertisers increases number of users
Congestion effect
Cash flow effect
Scale effect was determined to not be applicable[as noted there, the argument for this is completely wrong]
Indirect network effect has weak evidence, evidence exists that it doesn't apply, and even if it did apply, low click-through rate of ads shows that most consumers don't like ads anyway [what? This doesn't seem relevant?], and also, having a greater number of advertises leads to congestion and reduction in the value of the platform to advertisers [this is a reach; there is a sense in which this is technically true, but we could see then and now that platforms with few advertisers are extremely undesirable to advertises because advertisers generally don't want to advertise on a platform that full of low quality ads (and this also impacts the desire of users to use the platform)]
Cash flow effect not relevant because Microsoft isn't cash flow constrained, so cost isn't relevant [a funny comment to make because, not too long after this, Microsoft severely cut back investment in Bing because the returns weren't deemed to be worth it; it seems odd for economists to argue that, if you have a lot of money, the cost of things doesn't matter and ROI is irrelevant. Shouldn't they think about marginal cost and marginal revenue?]
[I stopped taking detailed notes at this point because taking notes that are legible to other people (as opposed to just for myself) takes about an order of magnitude longer, and I didn't think that there was much of interest here. I generally find comments of the form "I stopped reading at X" to be quite poor, in that people making such comments generally seem to pick some trivial thing that's unimportant and then declare and entire document to be worthless based on that. This pattern is also common when it comes to engineers, institutions, sports players, etc. and I generally find it counterproductive in those cases as well. However, in this case, there isn't really a single, non-representative, issue. The majority of the reasoning seems not just wrong, but highly disconnected from the on-the-ground situation. More notes indicating that the authors are making further misleading or incorrect arguments in the same style don't seem very useful. I did read the rest of the document and I also continue to summarize a few bits, below. I don't want to call them "highlights" because that would imply that I pulled out particularly interesting or compelling or incorrect bits and it's more of a smattering of miscellaneous parts with no particular theme]
There's a claim that removing restrictions on API interoperability may not cause short term problems, but may cause long-term harm due to how this shifts incentives and reduces innovation and this needs to be accounted for, not just the short-term benefit [in form, this is analogous to the argument Tyler Cowen recently made that banning non-competes reduces the incentives for firms to innovate and will reduce innovation]
The authors seem to like refer to advertisements and PR that any reasonable engineer (and I would guess reasonable person) would know are not meant to be factual or accurate. Similar to the PR argument above, they argue that advertising for Microsoft adCenter claims that it's easy to import data from AdWords, therefore the data portability issue is incorrect, and they specifically say that these advertising statements are "more credible than" other evidence
They also relied on some kind of SEO blogspam that restates the above as further evidence of this
The authors do not believe that Google Search and Google Local are complements or that taking data from Yelp or TripAdvisor and displaying it above search results has any negative impact on Yelp or TripAdvisor, or at least that "the burden of proof would be extremely difficult"
Other memos
[for these, I continued writing high-level summaries, not detailed summaries]
After the BE memo, there's a memo from Laura M. Sullivan, Division of Advertising Practices, which makes a fairly narrow case in a few dimensions, including "we continue to believe that Google has not deceived consumers by integrating its own specialized search results into its organic results" and, as a result, they suggest not pursuing further action.
There are some recommendations, such as "based on what we have observed of these new paid search results [referring to Local Search, etc.], we believe Google can strengthen the prominence and clarity of its disclosure" [in practice, the opposite has happened!]
[overall, the specific points presented here seems like ones a reasonable person could agree with, though whether or not these points are strong enough that they should prevent anti-trust action could be debated]
" Updating the 2002 Search Engine Letter is Warranted"
"The concerns we have regarding Google's disclosure of paid search results also apply to other search engines. Studies since the 2002 Search Engine letter was issued indicate that the standard methods search engines, including Google, Bing, and Yahoo!, have used to disclose their paid results may not be noticeable or clear enough for consumers. ²¹ For example, many consumers do not recognize the top ads as paid results ... Documents also indicate Google itself believed that many consumers generally do not recognize top ads as paid. For example, in June 2010, a leading team member of Google's in-house research group, commenting on general search research over time, stated: 'I don't think the research is inconclusive at all - there's definitely a (large) group of users who don't distinguish between sponsored and organic results. If we ask these users why they think the top results are sometimes displayed with a different background color, they will come up with an explanation that can range from "because they are more relevant" to "I have no idea" to "because Google is sponsoring them."' [this could've seemed reasonable at the time, but in retrospect we can see that the opposite of this has happened and ads are less distinguishable from search results than they were in 2012, likely meaning that even fewer consumers can distinguish ads from search results]
On the topic of whether or not Google should be liable for fraudulent ads such as ones for fake weight-loss products or fake mortgage relief services, "there is no indication so far that Google has played any role in developing or creating the search ads we are investigating" and Google is expending some effort to prevent these ads and Google can claim CDA immunity, so further investigation here isn't worthwhile
There's another memo from the same author on whether or not using other consumer data in conjunction with its search advertising business is unfair; the case is generally that this is not unfair and consumers should expect that their data is used to improve search queries
There's a memo from Ken Heyer (at the time, a Director of the Agency's Bureau of Economics)
Suggests having a remedy that seems "quite likely to do more good than harm" before "even considering serious filing a Complaint"
Seems to generally be in agreement with BE memo
On distribution, agrees with economist memo on unimportance of mobile and that Microsoft has good distribution on desktop (due to IE being default on 70% of PCs sold)
On API restrictions, mixed opinion
On mobile, mostly agrees with BE memo, but suggests getting an idea of how much Google pays for the right be default "since if default status is not much of an advantage we would not expect to see large payments being made" and also suggests it would be interesting to know how much switching from the default occurs
Further notes that mobile is only 8% of the market, too small to be significant [8% should've been factually incorrect. By late 2012, when this was written, mobile should've been 20% or more of queries; not sure why the economists are so wrong on so many of the numbers]
On vertical sites, agreement with data analysis from BE memo and generally agrees with BE memo
Another Ken Heyer memo
More strongly recommendations no action taken than previous memo, recommends against consent decree as well as litigation
Follow-up memo from BC staff (Barbara R. Blank et al.), recommending that staff negotiate a consent order with Google on mobile
Google has exclusive agreement with the 4 major U.S. wireless carriers and Apple to pre-install Google Search; Apple agreement requires exclusivity
Google default on 86% of devices
BC Staff recommends consent agreement to eliminate these exclusive agreements
According to Google documents mobile was 9.5% of Google queries in 2010, 17.3% in 2011 [note that this strongly contradicts the claim from the BE memo that mobile is only 8% of the market here]
Rapid growth shows that mobile distribution channel is significant, and both Microsoft and Google internal documents recognize that mobile will likely surpass desktop in the near future
In contradiction to their claims, Sprint and T-mobile agreements appear to mandate exclusivity, and AT&T agreement is de facto exclusive due to tiered revenue sharing arrangement; Verizon agreement is exclusive
Google business development manager Chris Barton: "So we know with 100% certainty due to contractual terms that: All Android phones on T-Mobile will come with Google as the only search engine out-of-the-box. All Android phones on Verizon will come with Google as the only search engine out-of-the-box. All Android phones on Sprint will come with Google as the only search engine out-of-the-box.I think this approach is really important otherwise Bing or Yahoo can come and steal away our Android search distribution at any time, thus removing the value of entering into contracts with them. Our philosophy is that we are paying revenue share"
Andy Rubin laid out a plan to reduce revenue share of partners over time as Google gained search dominance and Google has done this over time
Carriers would not switch even without exclusive agreement due to better monetization and/or bad PR
When wrapping up Verizon deal, Andy Rubin said "[i]f we can pull this off ... we will own the US market"
Memo from Willard K. Tom, General Counsel
"In sum, this may be a good case. But it would be a novel one, and as in all such cases, the Commission should think through carefully what it means."
Memo from Howard Shelanski, Director in Bureau of Economics
Mostly supports the BE memo and the memo from Ken Heyer, except on scraping, where there's support for the BC memo
By analogy to a case that many people in tech are familiar with, consider this exchange between Oracle counsel David Boies and Judge William Alsup on the rangeCheck function, which checks if a range is a valid array access or not given the length of an array and throws an exception if the access is out of range:
Boies: [argument that Google copied the rangeCheck function in order to accelerate development]
Alsup: All right. I have — I was not good — I couldn't have told you the first thing about Java before this trial. But, I have done and still do a lot of programming myself in other languages. I have written blocks of code like rangeCheck a hundred times or more. I could do it. You could do it. It is so simple. The idea that somebody copied that in order to get to market faster, when it would be just as fast to write it out, it was an accident that that thing got in there. There was no way that you could say that that was speeding them along to the marketplace. That is not a good argument.
Boies: Your Honor
Alsup: [cutting off Boies] You're one of the best lawyers in America. How can you even make that argument? You know, maybe the answer is because you are so good it sounds legit. But it is not legit. That is not a good argument.
Boies: Your Honor, let me approach it this way, first, okay. I want to come back to rangeCheck. All right.
Alsup: RangeCheck. All it does is it makes sure that the numbers you're inputting are within a range. And if they're not, they give it some kind of exceptional treatment. It is so — that witness, when he said a high school student would do this, is absolutely right.
Boies: He didn't say a high school student would do it in an hour, all right.
Alsup: Less than — in five minutes, Mr. Boies.
Boies previously brought up this function as a non-trivial piece of work and then argues that, in their haste, a Google engineer copied this function from Oracle. As Alsup points out, the function is trivial, so trivial that it wouldn't be worth looking it up to copy and that even a high school student could easily produce the function from scratch. Boies then objects that, sure, maybe a high school student could write the function, but it might take an hour or more and Alsup correctly responds that an hour is implausible and that it might take five minutes.
Although nearly anyone who could pass a high school programming class would find Boeis's argument not just wrong but absurd3, more like a joke than something that someone might say seriously, it seems reasonable for Boies to make the argument because people presiding over these decisions in court, in regulatory agencies, and in the legislature, sometimes demonstrate a lack of basic understanding of tech. Since my background is in tech and not law or economics, I have no doubt that this analysis will miss some basics about law and economics in the same way that most analyses I've read seem miss basics about tech, but since there's been extensive commentary on this case from people with strong law and economics backgrounds, I don't see a need to cover those issues in depth here because anyone who's interested can read another analysis instead of or in addition to this one.
Although this document is focused on tech, the lack of hands-on industry-expertise in regulatory bodies, legislation, and the courts, appears to cause problems in other industries as well. An example that's relatively well known due to a NY Times article that was turned into a movie is DuPont's involvement in the popularization of PFAS and, in particular, PFOA. Scientists at 3M and DuPont had evidence of the harms of PFAS going back at least to the 60s, and possibly even as far back as the 50s. Given the severe harms that PFOA caused to people who were exposed to it in significant concentrations, it would've been difficult to set up a production process for PFOA without seeing the harm it caused, but this knowledge, which must've been apparent to senior scientists and decision makers in 3M and DuPont, wasn't understood by regulatory agencies for almost four decades after it was apparent to chemical companies.
By the way, the NY Times article is titled "The Lawyer Who Became DuPont’s Worst Nightmare" and it describes how DuPont made $1B/yr in profit for years while hiding the harms of PFOA, which was used in the manufacturing process for Teflon. This lawyer brought cases against DuPont that were settled for hundreds of millions of dollars; according to the article and movie, the litigation didn't even cost DuPont a single year's worth of PFOA profit. Also, DuPont manage to drag out the litigation for many years, continuing to reap the profit from PFOA. Now that enough evidence has mounted against PFOA, Teflon is now manufactured using PFO2OA or FRD-903, which are newer and have a less well understood safety profile than PFOA. Perhaps the article could be titled "The Lawyer Who Became DuPont's Largest Mild Annoyance".
In the media, I've sometimes seen this framed as a conflict between tech vs. non-tech folks, but we can see analogous comments from people outside of tech. For example, in a panel discussion with Yale SOM professor Fiona Scott Morton and DoJ Antitrust Principal Deputy AAG Doha Mekki, Scott Morton noted that the judge presiding over the Sprint/T-mobile merger proceedings, a case she was an expert witness for, had comically wrong misunderstandings about the market, and that it's common for decisions to be made which are disconnected from "market realities". Mekki seconded this sentiment, saying "what's so fascinating about some of the bad opinions that Fiona identified, and there are many, there's AT&T Time Warner, Sabre Farelogix, T-mobile Sprint, they're everywhere, there's Amex, you know ..."
If you're seeing this or the other footnote in mouseover text and/or tied to a broken link, this is an issue with Hugo. At this point, I've spent more than an entire blog post's worth of effort working around Hugo breakage and am trying to avoid spending more time working around issues in a tool that makes breaking changes at a high rate. If you have a suggestion to fix this, I'll try it, otherwise I'll try to fix it when I switch away from Hugo.